3,077 Matching Annotations
  1. Sep 2023
    1. The implication for politics of the “mobile factors” approach is just this: thescarce factor (labor, in the above example) will favor restricting trade, and theabundant factor (capital, in the above example) will have incentives to favorliberalizing trade, no matter where in the economy those factors are employed.

      abundant resources will want free trade; scarce resource will want protectionism

    2. However, the interests of one of these groups offactor owners will in general be aligned with the interests of the owners of themobile factor(s). It seems probable that the stakes of the mobile factor ownerswill be smaller than those of the the specific factor owners.

      specific factors vs mobile factors

    3. But what if the capital used in the labor-intensiveindustry is different from the capital used in the capital- intensive industry? Tobring the example back down to earth, what if knitting machines cannot be usedto make microchips? Indeed, in many real world situations it seems intuitivelylikely that this will be the case: capital (or certain kinds of labor, for that matter)will not be able to flow easily from a declining sector to a rising sector. Adifferent set of assumptions is needed for this contingency. According to theassumptions of the Ricardo-Viner model (or “specific factors” model as it isoften called) factors of production are “specific” to a particular industry, andwhen that industry declines they cannot move to the rising industry

      RV is more about specific factors and interests in trade groups

    4. The assumption that factors are mobile between sectors of the economy is crucialto the derivation of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. It is only because capitalcan flow from the import-competing (labor-intensive industry) to the capital-intensive industry that it is able to enjoy the effect of the increased productionof the capital-intensive good.

      SS model assumes factors are mobile and money can flow between capital and labor seemlessly

    5. The logic may be somewhat involved, but the bottom lineis not: in this example of a capital-abundant country, labor loses and capitalwins from freer trade.

      labor loses and capital wins from free trade

    6. Combin-ing this prediction with the Stolper-Samuelson theorem yields the usual conclu-sion that, other things being equal, in a relatively capital-abundant country laborwill favor protection because it cannot be intensively used in exports, whilecapital will favor relatively free trade.

      SS+OH model is why organized labor in the US would oppose free trade

    7. Stolper-Samuelson or “mobile factors” approach (centralin Rogowski’s work) and the Ricardo-Viner or “specific factors” model (centralto Frieden and others).

      SS=mobile/tradable RV=special interest

    8. To bring it down to earth, a one milliondollar lobbying contribution from G M will likely have a large effect on tradepolicy. A ten dollar contribution from an individual auto consumer will havevirtually no effect. Thus even though the cost of the auto consumer’s contributionis negligible, the expected benefits are even more negligible.*

      this feels so atomizing and i wonder if workarounds have been proposed

    9. Two answers to the puzzle are possible. First, there maybe per person transaction costs in organizing groups. Second, if policy outcomesare probabilistic, members of large groups with small per person stakes andcontributions may suppose that their own contributions will be insignificant tothe political outcome and therefore not make them. On the other hand, membersof smaller groups, with their larger stakes and contributions per person, may seethat their contribution has a non-negligible impact on the likelihood that a policywill be enacted, and therefore they will make their contributions.

      this makes sense as a balancing of forces for special interest, though i have to wonder how this works outside of a population dimension. like if somewhere is super diffuse like mongolia then what happens? Information can't travel as easy

    10. A protectionist measure provides large benefits to a small number of people, andcauses a very great number of consumers a slight loss. This circumstance makes iteasier to put a protection measure in practice

      ease of policy enaction. Would there be a way to fix this?

    11. We conclude by showing the importance of distinguishingthe intensity of demand (how much you want something) from collective actionsproblems (the relative cost of organizing politically to get something, howevermuch you want it) and we speculate about the effects of factor mobility on thedifficulty of collective action and what impact this has on the politics of tradepolicy

      cost-benefit of lobbying. Intensity of demand vs cost of getting it

    12. may become weighing the good of the many, which isoften served by relatively free trade, against the good of the powerful few whichmay be served by restricting trade.

      conspirartorial

    13. In domestic politics the conflict over these distributional consequences willreflect the trade policy coalitions that form around shared interests in liberali-zation as opposed to protection. Whether trade policies are taken to be chosendemocratically or imposed from above, whether those coalitions are engaged invote mobilization or protest, the balance between the opposed coalitions favoringfreer trade and those favoring protection creates the “demand” by society forliberalization or protection.

      this feels like a push and pull between consumers and producers, is that a correct framework?

    14. Anyone theorizing about “trading states”(states of trading societies) should consider the state’s problem of how to weighthe aggregate

      i guess a larger question i have is that, if so much of our history as humans has involved city states, trading, commerce, mercantilism, and all these other ways of trying to make trade work FOR us, then why is it now we have become so scareD?

    15. Trade typically offers cheaper goods, with more choice for consumers andthe greatest economic output for society as a whole. But at the same time, it isalso very disruptive to individuals’ lives, tying their incomes to the vagaries ofinternational markets. In so doing, trade affects the distribution of wealth withinthe domestic economy, raising questions of who gets relatively more or less, andwhat they can do about it politically.

      debate over opulence vs who gets the slice of the pie. The idea of being subject to exogenous shocks is understandably scary

    Annotators

    1. whichemphasizes the influence exerted by special-interest groups on policy makers by means ofpolitical contribution

      G-H focuses on special interest groups

    2. Forthis reason, we were surprised to find that thestrict version of the G-H model is not "grossly"inconsistent with the data.

      GH model somewhat backed by data

    3. Tests of the strict versions of trade models tra-ditionally yield disastrous results for the theo-ries under investigation-the poor empiricalperformance of the strict version of theHeckscher-Ohlin model is a good example

      HO model does poorly

    4. Of some interest, we believe, is also ourestimate of a key structural parameter of themodel, namely the weight attached by the gov-ernment to social welfare. We estimate thisweight to be many times higher than the weightattached to contribution

      more important is social welfare

    5. e measurement prob-lems associated with trade elasticities should not biasour results given that elasticities do not appear on theright-hand side of the esimating equa

      elasticities fine

    6. Presumably,industries that are experiencing high unemploy-ment rates tend to be more vocal in the politicalarena, and manage to obtain more trade protec-tio

      unemploymeny could lead to more protectionism

    7. ur interpretation of this finding is that theUnited States is relatively open to trade, evenwhen nontariff barriers are accounted for

      US is relatively open to free trade

    8. Thus, the positive correlation between importpenetration and protection documented in pre-vious papers does not constitute evidenceagainst the mod

      import penetration leads to more protectionism

    9. heseworks take a reduced-form approach, in thesense of not being guided by a theoreticalmode

      is a theoretical model even necessary

    10. The model's predictionswith respect to the relevant coefficient signsare as follows: (i) trade protection should behigher in industries represented by a lobby,and in industries with a lower import elastic-ity; (ii) within the subset of organized indus-tries, protection should be higher in industrieswith lower import penetration, whereas in thegroup of nonorganized sectors, protectionshould increase with import pen

      (1) trade protection should be higher in industries with lobbying power / low import elasticiity (2) protection should be higher in industries with lower penetration

    11. yields clear predictions for the cross-sectional struc-ture of import barriers

      cross-sectional more relevant

    Annotators

    1. We concur with Jenkins, who points out that "the existence ofa crisis is no guarantee that a government will respond, and more importantly,that it will be successful in convincing interest groups that 'something must bedone.' "

      crises do not necessitate a government response

    2. Democracies choose lowerlevels of trade barriers, even when holding many other factors constant

      main take away

    3. his variable(IMF) was never significant. Increases in external pressure via the IMF have littlemeasurable effect on trade policy, and when they do (in the regressions on Sachs-Warner openness), their effect is to increase the closure of the economy, not to openit

      IMF actually is insignificant / helps to close the economy

    4. These variables do not seemto matter significantly, either independently or jointly. Countries may respond dif-ferently to crises, sometimes raising trade barriers and other times lowering them.These results are not unexpected. Many claims about the role of crises come fromcase studies that often select on the dependent variable; that is, they explore casesof economic reform and often find that crises (of varying types) existed as well.But they rarely look at the cases where countries experienced crises and did notreform.106 As noted earlier, the debt crisis of the early 1980s did not lead to tradeliberalization, but to greater closure. The effects of crises may be highly contin-gent on the environment

      crises may not be as relevant as previously anticipated

    5. We also lagged the main alternatives to our argument: the crisis variables(EC CRISIS and BP CRISIs) and an external pressure variable (IMF) for two and threeperiods for both dependent variable

      adding a variable to address the IMF and economic crises

    6. Our central hypothesis is that more democratic countries should have fewer tradebarriers, ceteris paribus; an increase in democracy should prompt a reduction intrade barriers.

      central hypothesis of the paper

    7. n sum, in developing countries where autocratic governments depend on sup-port from a small selectorate and thus are not responsive to the overall population,the governments can employ extensive protectionism.

      developing=autocratic=protectionist democratization breaks up old coalitions

    8. tal. Those with "voting" rights in autocracies thus ownabove-average levels of capital, and benefit the most from high levels of protec-tion

      autocrats benefit the most from protectionism, outsized role in the selectorate

    9. ralization? Democratization ma movement toward majority rule with universal suffrage in contested eleWe call the group of actors who participate in the selection of political"the selectorate," following the terminology of Bueno d

      selectorate=those who can participate in democracy

    10. The democratization ofmany East Central European countries, such as Poland and Hungary, was fol-lowed by economic reform, including massive trade liberalization.4

      what about shock therapy though? Could it be it wasn't democratization alone?

    11. In no country were trade barriers reduced to zero, and thus weare not arguing that protectionist interest groups no longer mattered. But indemocratizing countries they mattered less than before, and thus leaders could lib-eralize more than previously

      protectionist interest groups became less powerful under democratization

    12. . Many scholars agree that in large parts ofLatin America, Africa, and Asia, the groups that gained from ISI were urban own-ers of industry (that is, capitalists) and urban, higher-skilled and often unionizedworkers (more capital-endowed workers); the losers tended to be less-skilled, poorerworkers, generally rural ones.24Even the debt crisis of the early 1980s was unable to shake this coalition fromits economically inefficient policies. Many scholars report that protection increasedin the wake of the debt crisis, especially in Latin America.

      debunking the economic crisis theory

    13. The conventional wisdom, however, has been that democracy is not propitious foreconomic reform, and indeed that nondemocratic countries should be more likelyto liberalize, as Chile in the 1970s suggests. As Geddes summarizes, "until recently,it was widely accepted that democracies, especially fragile, uninstitutionalized newdemocracies have difficulty carrying out economic liberalization because its costsmake it unpopular and hence politically suicidal to elected officials.

      conventional belief before the 1990s

    14. xplanations for this change have emphasized three factors. Some scholars claimthat economic crises have forced countries to reform and liberalize. Others haveclaimed that external pressures from the United States, Western countries in gen-eral, or international institutions, such as the World Trade Organization (WTO),IMF, and World Bank, are responsible. Finally, the spread of neoliberal policyideas is often credited with bringing economic liberalization. We examine theseclaims with respect to trade policy and introduce another factor that we think isimportant and underappreciat

      three ideas 1. economic crises 2. IMF and WB and US 3. neoliberalism economic

    15. mocracy. We argue that these two trendsare related: democratization of the political system reduces the ability of governments to use trade barriers as a strategy for building political support. Political lead-ers in labor-rich countries may prefer lower trade barriers as democ

      main argument: free trade and democraticization are related

    1. enators whomatch a voter's trade policy preference can expect to see only a minimal boost inthe probability of re-election; while those who do not pay a minimal cost in votes

      not super important for re-election then

    2. Additionally, higher levels of education, a proxy for high-skilled workers andthus voters with theoretically predicted free-trading preferences, are linked with ahigher propensity to provide an answer. However, there is not a significant differ-ence between the likelihood of the answers being correct or incorrect. Regionally,those in the Midwest and the South are far more likely to both offer an answerand provide a correct answer.

      Midwest and South more politically involved?

    3. Second and unexpectedly, given the usefulnessof union organizations for information distribution, union membership increasesthe likelihood of not providing an answer, even after controlling for factors suchas education

      maybe bc the union can help guide them on who to vote for alleviating the need to research the posititons of individual candidates?

    4. 4 In each case, the difference between trade policy and all other issues wasstatistically significant

      people mostly don't keep track of trade records for poltiicans

    5. y. CAFTA attracted a politically wide spec-trum of opponents: liberal presidential candidate Ralph Nader,19 conservative pres-idential candidate Pat Buchanan,20 and the Nobel Prize-winning economist JosephStiglitz,21 among others, all spoke out against CAFTA. Unlike many other billsthat mix together multiple policy areas, the CAFTA legislation focused almostexclusively on trade issues, making interpretation of politicians' vote choice eas-ier for voters. If voters do not hold politicians accountable over a recent, high-profile piece of trade legislation such as CAFTA, they are unlikely to do so formore typical bil

      CAFTA was unique in that it was economically not super important but the media took it as a serious issue

    6. hus, salienceembraces two concepts: knowledge of deviations of the candidate's position fromthe voter's preferred policy and the relative importance the voter places on this

      salience= 1. knowledge of one's own views in relation to the candidate 2. importance placed on this deviation

    7. A finding of low salience in terms of knowledge or importance combined withlow accountability of politicians on trade policy issues would suggest the need tore-evaluate voter-inclusive models of trade policy, especially those with a genericcall to the voter.

      rethinking of we can rely on public opinion?

    8. hese models agree that votersmatter, but diverge on which voters matter. In majority voting models, character-izations by economic interest of the voter may differ, but once preferences andinstitutional rules are defined, aggregation is as simple as counting. Alternatively,influential voter models focus on variations in saliency - generally characterizedby diffuse versus specific interests - which may lead some voters to care moreabout the issue, to be more knowledgeable, and thus to hold politicians account-able for their policy decision

      influential voter models--saliency is prooritized

    9. the day. The article finds trade policy salience to berelatively low in terms of stated importance, in voters' knowledge of their representatives' policy positions, and in its effect on voters' propensity to vote for the incumbent. The low salience of trade policy, particularly among highly affected groupcalls into question voter-driven models of

      could it be one of those issues that raises in importance when things are overall going well?

    10. ctorate. Using data from a survey of 36,501 potetial voters in the 2006 U.S. midterm congressional elections, this article explores tsalience of trade policy for voters as a whole and for populations predicted to bemost affected by changing trad

      2006 midterm was a landslide for democrats

    1. 8 Likewise, when unemployment isemphasized in local and national media, individuals' perceptions of the state ofunemployment also become more negative.69 Any tendency for the press to placegreater emphasis on the harmful impact of trade and less emphasis on the benefi-cial impact might help to account for the negatively skewed sociotropic percep-tions shown in Figure 1.

      media and the slant of the media plays a huge role, so if the media were more positive instead of caught in a negative feedback loop would we see a lot of change?

    2. . First, many have found that mass media coverage of the economy playsan important role in forming these perceptions

      role of media (FOX) on discussing free trade

    3. Consequently, the effects of education reflect differences in attitudesabout the extent to which the United States should take an activist stance in inter-national affairs and a general tendency to think less of out-groups relative toin-groups

      education lessens the perception of in vs out groups

    4. The estimated coefficients of the two variablestapping exposure to ideas about the benefits of trade are both positive, econo-mists' view of trade has a statistically significant effect, whereas the influenceof economics class is marginally significant (/? = .105). Nonetheless, economicknowledge has a small impact on trade attitudes: taking an economics class orunderstanding that economists argue that free trade is beneficial increases the pre-dicted value of the KN dependent variable by only 2 to 3 percent, holding con-stant the remaining variables in th

      economics isnt super influential, btu some presence

    5. Our initial results - in the first column of Tables 1 , 2, and 3 - provide clear evi-dence of a gender gap, with women holding more protectionist attitudes than m

      women are more protectionist than men, democrats more protectionist than republicans.

      I'd want to revisit this. Maybe it's not really about the party line and something deeper?

    6. t. Individuals who attended graduate school are much more supportiveof open trade than both people with only a high school education and those withsome college educat

      again, the idea of debt is of interest for me here.

    7. , "In your current (or most recent) job,what kind of work do you do?

      I'd love to know in this about the amount of personal debt one holds. If a person has more debt how would that modify their views?

    8. Our key independent variables fall into three broad categories: (1) indicators ofthe individual characteristics suggested by the factor endowments and specific fac-tors models, (2) indicators of respondents' perceptions of how trade influencestheir family's financial conditions as well as the country as a whole, and (3) indi-cators tapping potential noneconomic influences on trade preferences, includingnationalism, ethnocentrism, and attitudes toward intervention in the a

      1: individual characteristics financially 2. family/community 3. softer individual identities

    9. Thus, to the extentthat trade preferences are similar to attitudes toward other aspects of economicpolicy, they will stem from people's perceptions of the collective impact that tradepolicy has on the nation. This pattern has been dubbed sociotropic influence becauseof the tendency it suggests for relying on collective-level information rather thanpersonal experien

      collective information over personal experience

    10. Empirical research suggests that education affects political pref-erences in at least two ways: (1) through occupational prominence and position insocial networks, and (2) through cognitive proficiency and analytical ability

      educational impact is 2 fold: 1. occupational prominence and social networking 2. cognitive abilities

    11. Equally, an individual employed in a nontradedsector of the economy should be more protrade than someone employed in anindustry that faces substantial competition from foreign import

      the idea of trade vs non trade sectors is useful, but what about people who work at say McDonalds or in SQL? Are they expected to support free trade since they work in a service not in a manufacturing capacity?

    12. Open trade increases the demand for skilledworkers, since the United States has a comparative advantage in the production ofgoods that use this input intensively. As the demand for such workers rises, so dotheir wages. Conversely, heightened trade decreases the demand for low-skilled laborin the United States and depresses its wage rate since goods produced using suchlabor intensively can be produced more efficiently abroad.5

      ok so yes this makes sense but outside of the US would the inverse happen where free trade would incenticize low skilled workers to produce manufactured goods? If that's the case, what breaks those countries out of their development cycle?

    13. psychologically based models that address how individuals process informationabout the economy, and how they form attitudes about people and places beyondtheir borders

      adding psychology into the mix

    14. Consistent withprevious research on the impact of self-interest on policy attitudes, our data showlittle support for either the factor endowments or the specific factors model. Bycontrast, perceptions of how trade affects the country as a whole - what are oftenreferred to as "sociotropic" perceptions - play a substantial role in shaping atti-tudes about foreign commerce, a role that is largely independent of self-interest.

      sociotropic is more relevant than factor endowments etc

    15. First, the factor endowments approach emphasizes that, in a given country,trade benefits those individuals who own factors of production that are in abun-dant supply relative to the remainder of the world, and harms owners of factorsthat are in scarce suppl

      Factor Endowments Approach: emphasizes that trade benefits individuals who own the factors of production that are more common in that country relative to the global average

    16. works. We find little support for either of these mod-els using two representative national surveys of A

      these models find little utility on the average american -- perhaps this shows most americans are uninformed?

    17. The specific factors or Ricardo-Viner model posits that trade preferences depend onthe industry in which a person

      RV model is more concerned with industry

    18. factor endowments or Heckscher-Ohlin model posits that these preferences are affected primarily by a

      HO model is determined by a person's skills to inform their opinions on international trade

    1. The likely opponents of globalization among firmsare, in contrast, large in number, relatively weak in their pref-erences, and lacking in political powe

      small firms lack access to political power

    2. We propose, then,that the rise of intra-industry trade—and of the superstar ex-porter divorced from the concerns of the weaker firms in hisindustry—has contributed to the steady erosion of trade bar-riers over the past several decades

      the intensity of charmed superstars pushes policy, small minority speaking for most

    3. Concern about import com-petition and export opportunities are positively correlated,suggesting the importance of intra-industry trade flows.

      intra-industry trade flows important since the concern about import is correlated positively with external trade concerns

    4. We find that attitudes are bestexplained by firm-level characteristics regardless of industryfeatures.

      firm characteristics > industry features

    5. Finally, it is worth noting that firms generally rated changesin wage rates, whether among skilled or unskilled workers,as the least important determinants of their trade attitudes.Among responding firms, 73% and 78% of respondents re-ported that changes in skilled and unskilled workers wageswere “not important” or only “somewhat important” in eval-uating trade policy changes.

      wages not important to policy debate on trade -- odd

    6. Firms that feel that their products are easy toreplace with varieties made by competitors are extremelyworried about the impact of import competition; firms thatfeel that their products are more difficult to find substitutesfor are much less concerned.

      firms that feel that their products are replacable are woried about foreign competition

    7. A very strong pattern emerges: only the largest and mostsuccessful exporting firms consider trade politics to beworthy of interest and expending their political capital. Ex-port status alone does not generate such interest, but a highintensity of export participation does

      only most succesful exporting firms care about lobbying for free trade

    8. Firm-level factors, especially export ac-tivity and intensity, are strongly predictive of support fortrade liberalization, while various proxies for industry-widecomparative advantage are not.

      export activity predictive of support for liberalization

    9. . Lobbying is also common-place: 35.9% of our respondents reported contacting the Of-fice of the President, the Legislative Assembly, or the Ministryof Foreign Trade (COMEX) to discuss public policy.

      very active civil society

    10. Prediction 2. The largest exporters will consider tradepolicy to be a much more significant issue than eithersmaller exporters or nonexporters. This preference inten-sity will also manifest itself in patterns of information-seeking and lobbying on trade policy, where we expectthe largest firms to be most active.

      larger exporters can pivot to looking to the exterior unlike smaller firms

    11. The reach of our theory is limited to industrieswith some measure of product differentiation, and we wouldexpect that where products are entirely homogeneous anindustry’s preferences over trade would look like the theRicardo-Viner predictions, that is, driven by industry-levelfactors rather than firms’ ability to export.

      issue of homogeneity within some markets - limit to the model

    12. However, among all firms that exported, thelargest 1% (about 1,700 firms total) accounted for 80.9% of allUS exports (Bernard et al. 2009).

      firms that export are concentrated

    13. Less productive firmsgenerally must charge higher prices in order to recoup theirhigher costs, and they therefore are less likely to find exportmarkets for their relatively expensive products once tradecosts are included (

      inefficient markets may not like free trade

    14. We then turn to testing our predictions. We expect to seefirm-level characteristics—export status, and especially export-intensity—to be positively correlated with support for tradeliberalization.

      more import intensity=more support for free trade

    15. The remainder of firms—who are notwinners from liberalization—are, in contrast, small in size andmany in number, and they face costs diffused over a broadrange of firms.

      diffused benefits

    16. These firms are the core constituents for trade liberalization,and their enormous share of export sales give them the in-centive, intensity, and resources to supercharge their pro-trade political activity.

      superstar firms while most small ones struggle

    17. we find that firmfeatures are generally more important predictors of attitudes toward trade liberalization than industry-wide compar-ative advantage.

      firm behaviors (specific firms health and superstar exporters) are important to the free trade public support story

    Annotators

    1. s shown in column (3) of Table 7, pridein a country’s democracy is positively correlated withpro-trade attitudes.

      proud of democracy=pro trade

    2. Whatever thereason, the bottom line that emerges from this regression is that the main cleavage inpreference formation over trade lies not between the two tradable sectors but betweentradables and non-tradables.

      tradable v non tradable

    3. he poorest countries in the sample – Bangladesh, Nigeria, Armenia,Georgia – are those where more skill is associated with less pro-trade views. None ofthe richer countries exhibits this reversal.

      in the poorer countries, more skill is associated with less pro trade views, suggesting income for countries is a huge factor and that this relationship between skill and pro-free trade sentiment eventually inverts

    4. The result is striking: there is a very strong and tightrelationship between a country’s per-capita GDP and the magnitude of the correspond-ing estimated marginal eDect of education (the coePcient of per capita GDP is 1.53percentage points per US$10,000, robust t-statistic = 4:97, signi/cant at 1% level). Thericher a country, the more positive is the impact of a marginal increase of educationon the probability of pro-trade attitudes.

      education is an accelerative force for pro free trade sentiment

    5. ccording to the Stolper–Samuelsontheorem, skilled workers in all sectors of the economy will gain and unskilled workerswill lose.

      stolper-samuelson is more black and white and class focused

    6. We shall keep age, gender, citizenship andeducation as controls in all speci/cations

      what is kept as controls

    7. Older individuals appear tobe more protectionist, but the estimates are not always signi/cant. 17 Citizenship in thecountry is negatively associated withpro-trade sentiments, while political aPliationwith the right has a positive and signi/cant impact on pro-trade attitudes

      political affiliation with the right is pro-trade GIRL WHAT

    8. n other words, communitarian-patrioticvalues tend to foster protectionist attitudes, but this tendency is moderated when thebroader institutions of society are perceived to be working well

      broader institutional confidence = more support for free trade

    9. For example, individuals who consider themselves part of the upperclasses tend to be more favorable to trade than those who consider themselves to befrom the lower classes.

      class identification is malleable and this is a rlly cool point

    10. We /nd support for the speci/c-factors model as well. In particular, individuals em-ployed in import-competing industries are more likely to be in favor of trade restrictions(compared to individuals in non-traded sectors).

      import-competing industries

    11. High degrees of neighborhood attachment and nationalism/patriotismare associated withprotectionist tendencies.

      v true

    12. relative economic status

      like in their cities/towns?

    13. e /nd that pro-trade prefer-ences are signi/cantly and robustly correlated with an individual’s level of human capital, in themanner predicted by the factor endowments model. Preferences over trade are also correlated withthe trade exposure of the sector in which an individual is employed: individuals in non-tradedsectors tend to be the most pro-trade, while individuals in sectors with a revealed comparativedisadvantage are the most protectionist

      this all feels like it confirms existing literature already. Only tyhe idea of traded vs non-traded sectors.

    Annotators

    1. The other message of our empirical analysis is that political-economy modelersmight consider asset ownership.

      could this be expanded into equities etc

    2. In all eight models reported in Table 6, our estimates of the effect of countytrade exposure on individual homeowners’ trade preferences are consistent withour theoretical expectations. We estimate that, for homeowners, an increase incounty trade exposure from its sample mean to one standard deviation above itsmean increases the probability of supporting trade restrictions by between 0.029and 0.039.

      being in a county w trade disadvantage

    3. For example, Model 1 indicatesthat increasing Occupation Wage from its mean to one standard deviation above itsmean reduces the probability of supporting trade restrictions by 0.074 on average

      strong showing for wage determining support for free trade

    4. The results of our logistic regressions for Models 1 through 8 strongly supportthe hypothesis that individuals’ skill levels determine trade-policy preferences.Little evidence is found consistent with the hypothesis that industry of employ-ment influences policy preferences.

      no evidence that indsutry of employment influences policy preferences

    5. To summarize: in regions with a high concentration of activity in comparative-disadvantage sectors, homeowners should oppose freer trade because its contrac-tionary effects in the region tend to reduce homeowners’ welfare by lowering6housing demand and thus housing values

      michigan shouldn't like free trade AND should have bad housing

    6. Trade policy is one of the forces affecting the level of regional economicactivity. Freer trade tends to shrink comparative-disadvantage industries andexpand comparative-advantage ones

      regions with comparative disadvantage are more susceptable to homelessness

    7. To summarize, in HO models factors evaluate trade policy based on their factortype while in RV models factors evaluate trade policy based on their industry ofemployment. What do these two models predict about trade-policy preferences inthe United States? Many studies (e.g., Leamer, 1984) have documented that theUnited States is well endowed with more-skilled labor relative to the rest of theworld. According to the HO model, then, in the United States more-skilledworkers should support freer trade while less-skilled workers should oppose it. Incontrast, the RV model predicts that U.S. workers employed in comparative-advantage sectors should support freer trade while those in comparative-dis-advantage sectors should oppose it.

      HO tends US

    8. Second, our units of observation are individuals, not more-aggregatedgeographic units such as counties or Congressional districts.

      focuses on ppl

    9. Analyzing 1991 Congressional votes on granting presidential‘‘fast track’’ trade-negotiating authority, Kaempfer and Marks (1993) find Housevotes significantly correlated with the average wage in House districts (but not sofor Senate votes and average state wages).

      issue of federalism

    10. Using an individual-level survey of Canadianvoters, Beaulieu (1996) finds that factor type rather than industry of employmentbest explains votes in the 1988 Canadian federal election, an election widelyregarded as a national referendum on the Canadian–U.S. Free-Trade Agreement(CAFTA).

      clear differences between countries in their factor vs indusrtry supports for free trade

    11. Assets like housing do not fit into standard trade theory because theyare neither currently employed factors nor currently produced goods. We find thatindependent of factor type or industry of employment, home ownership in countieswith a manufacturing mix concentrated in comparative-disadvantage

      home ownership is a factor, not a liquid asset

    12. First, we find that factor type dominatesindustry of employment in explaining support for trade barriers. Lower skill,measured by education or average occupation earnings, is strongly correlated withsupport for new trade barriers.

      lower skill=hates free trade; high skill supports free trade

    13. Ricardo–Viner (RV)framework where some or all factors cannot move to other sectors

      RV=factors cannot move to other sectors

    14. In contrast, in a Heckscher–Ohlin (HO)framework where factors move costlessly across sectors, factor incomes tend tovary by factor type.

      HO framework: factors of production move costlessly across borders

    15. Second, we find that home ownership also matters forindividuals’ trade-policy preferences.

      2: home ownership determines support for international trade

    16. First, we find that factor type dominates industry of employment inexplaining support for trade barriers.

      1: what industry someone works in will determine their feelings on free trade

    1. nternational institutions can performinformation-provision functions that allow states to overcome collective-action problemsand therefore have an impact on patterns of behavior, even if these institutions do notregulate, enforce, or otherwise take on the characteristics associated with “strong”institutions on the domestic level.

      information-provision functions

    2. s Keohane’s title suggests, much of the early workon institutions developed in reaction to the predictions of early hegemonic stability theorythat international economic cooperation should plummet as U.S. power declined in the1970s. However, in many areas of the international economy cooperation appeared to bestable or to increase. At the same time, the international economy had become morehighly institutionalized, with organizations such as the GATT and IMF gainingprominence.

      international institutions keep cooperation even in multipolar world? Is this really something we can prove? How can we stress test it?

    3. A second type of uncertainty in IPE is about the relationship between policies andoutcomes, or causal relationships.17 Some refer to this type of uncertainty as lack ofprecise knowledge about “the state of the wor

      this or unintended consequences

    4. n most settings, signals sent by states are most effective inchanging the beliefs of others if these signals are costly. Otherwise, intended recipientsare likely to dismiss signals as cheap talk. Analyses of some international monetaryregimes sees them in this light, as commitment to a fixed exchange rate or a currencyunion involves a political cost that sends a signal about the intentions of governments(Giavazzi and Pagano 1988). However, in some circumstances even cheap talk can be aneffective signa

      signals + cheap talk work in IR to align IPE goals

    5. To simplify somewhat, two types ofuncertainty are important for IPE: uncertainty about the preferences of others, and aboutcausal relationships

      two types of uncertainty in IPE: preferences of others and causal relationships

    6. Governments of large countries aremore likely to be protectionist than governments of small countries, for example; thelatter are likely to value exchange-rate stability more highly than the latter

      this feels untrue

    7. Treating states as units – although not identical units– scholars ask how the constraints and opportunities offered by the international system,and processes of interaction with other states, influence decisions and outcomes

      i understand the impulse with units but if some countries do not fully control their countries what happens then?

    8. strategic interaction at theinternational level.

      strategic internaractions on the international level

    9. The recent upsurge of interest in standards that relate to trade – environmental,labor, health and safety – has also led to the creation of delegated institutionalmechanisms to deal with these issues, such as the independent agencies established underthe auspices of NAFTA. In the European Union, trade policymaking is delegated to theEuropean Commission and, within this, to industry-specific groups that includerepresentatives from many member states. Trade policy is not unique.

      does this create a new institution that is theoretically shared among all NAFTA countries?

    10. A constitutional structure, for example,that gives trade policy authority to the more localist legislature will produce differentoutcomes from one that delegates all trade policymaking to the executive

      federalism / unitary and other relevant decisions. Does nationalization of politics typically associate with more liberalization?

    11. Institutions perform two general functions: aggregation and delegation. Someinstitutions aggregate interests in ways that affect the ability of groups to organize and theweight they will have in the political process. Other institutions delegate decision-making authority to particular actors, similarly changing the weight of various interests in

      institutions condense and then disseminate interests

    12. Variation in the organization of economic interests has important implications forthe making of policy. An obvious example is the difference between labor ormanagement interests that are organized on sectoral as opposed to class lines. Wheresectoral forms of association prevail, there is likely to be much more pressure forparticularistic policies: trade protection, export subsidies, controls on or subsidies toforeign investment. Where class politics prevails, policies are less likely to focus onindustry-specific benefits and more likely to involve concerns of broader interest to laboror capital as a whole.

      class vs sectoral differences

    13. Public opinion may be hostile to devaluation, but even more hostile to the expenditurereductions and tax increases necessary to defend the exchange rate

      yes true but even then how did we have a wave of pro-austerity candidates in some countries? This feels like they are assuming voters are informed

    14. Another possibility is to focus not onsociety as a whole, but on the median voter, and attempt to establish the expected policypreferences of such pivotal actors.4 This is standard in studies of income redistribution,where it is common to assume that the net expected benefits of redistributive policies onthe median voter will determine their electoral viability.5 The generally applicable pointis that if the median voter – more generally, the politically pivotal portion of the public –can, roughly speaking, be identified, it may also be possible to identify the policypreferences of this segment of the population

      i feel this section is a bit iffy since some populations are very diverse, so what is the functional role of a median voter?

    15. More recent developments look at scale economies, typicallyto argue that larger firms should prefer more open trade

      larger firms will prefer open trade. So, domestic firm structures will come into play with international trade considerations

    16. In this domestic analysis, we identify three analytical steps. First, scholarsspecify the economic interests at stake. Second, they characterize the organization ofthese interests. Third, they investigate how these interests are mediated through politicalinstitutions.

      1) define interests at stake 2) characterize organization of interests 3) investigation how these go through institutions

      Public opinion vs policy (ppl irrational about inflation)

      How do we balance between public opinion and academia in this domestic equation?

    17. that pairs of democracies have moresuccess in lowering barriers to trade than pairs that match a democracy with an autocracy.Statistical work bears out this proposition.

      democracies are better at collaborating -- information symmetry Rosendorf 2000

    18. Here, two factors get the most attention: theinterests of the legislature, particularly how its ideal point differs from that of thepresident; and the degree of uncertainty associated with international negotiations.

      Milner and uncertainty 1. legislature wants vs president 2. precarious nature of international negotiation

    19. Jack Snyder called “synergy”

      Jack Snyder-Synergy

    20. ynergy represents new possibilities that open up as the result of interactionbetween the domestic and international levels, and might occur when negotiators are ableto use international negotiations to create previously unattainable outcomes, thusenlarging their domestic win-sets

      aligning international and domestic motives. Why does discourse seem to focus on misalignment rather than alignment? How do we make sense of this?

    21. For example, Rodrik (1997) hasargued that economic integration has reduced the ability of governments to tax capital,thus limiting the scope for government policies to deal with the social dislocations thatglobalization itself creates. Others believe that these effects are less limiting, stillallowing for different national economic-policy paths (Garrett 1998). All thesearguments share a common causal approach connecting the international and domesticlevels: globalization, understood as developments in international economic integration,alter the choices available to national governments, which in turn affects national policy(and, one could continue, international outcomes).

      globalization with Rodrik, what does IPE think about populism?

    22. to sustain controls on cross-borderinvestment.

      where do we see the role of capital in bringing the world together and fundamentally challenging sovereignty? The flow of cash removes sovereignty from states

    23. In addition to affecting domestic interests, the international economy might alsoaffect domestic institutions, for example by making a previously feasible policy difficultto sustain.

      international factors can imperil domestic policies -- capital controls

    24. nterests are aggregated through institutions, which also delegateresponsibility for decisionmaking to particular actors

      institutions as chambers of interest -- is this the case everywhere? The idea of information is a complex one

    25. Like all of IPE, the interaction of domestic and international conditions can beanalyzed in terms of three factors: interests, institutions, and information

      domestic and international conditions can be arranged by 1. institutions 2. interests 3. information

      these feel quite broad, while i understand their utility is there any push to make these more specific?

    26. The core of the domestic-international connection is the impact of domesticinstitutions and interests on international interaction, and vice versa. Our ultimate goal isa simultaneous understanding of this mutual causation, recognizing feedback effects atboth levels -- a general equilibrium model, rather than a partial equilibrium one in whichone level is held fixed while the other varies

      hard to reconcile and make theoretical frameworks to encompass domestic-international relations and how they inform one another

    27. foreign direct investmen

      Dambisa Moyo

    28. The research frontier for IPE is thus defined in termsof empirical puzzles as well as a theoretical agenda, although we do not cover more thana sample of the empirical work that has been done over past decades. One relativelywell-developed empirical subject area, from which we draw many of our illustrativeexamples, is international trade.

      international trade and monetary relations are two subjects that can be categorized as IPE

    29. Scholars typically see alternative approaches ascomplementary or applying under different, specifiable, conditions. Other disagreementsmight be debates about the relative weights that we should attribute to alternativeexplanatory variables. These types of scholarly differences are the hallmark of a maturefield of research that has moved from sweeping attempts at self-definition to formulatingrefutable analytical claims and evaluating their fit with empirical regularities.

      more policy, less larger theoretical debates - does this mean we can say that this field of research axiomatically accepts certain principals, if so, what are they?

    30. he biggest challengefacing the field is understanding the simultaneous interaction of domestic andinternational factors in determining foreign economic policies and international economicoutcomes

      issue of weighing internal vs external factors in what determins countries' foreign economic policies

    Annotators

  2. May 2023
    1. A study of the height ofMexican children whose mothers worked in ma-quiladoras (export factories) in Mexico dramaticallyillustrates the power of a good job. 11 Maquiladorasgenerally have the reputation of being exploitativeand paying poor wages.

      when jobs materialize it helps create a middle class and improve outcomes for people

    2. This is the paradox of the poor and their busi-nesses: They are energetic and resourceful andmanage to make a lot out of very little.

      businesses are too undifferentiated

    3. During the two hours we spent with this house-hold, we saw two customers. One bought a single ci-garette, the other a few sticks of incense. Clearly,the marginal return of increasing the size of the in-ventory a little was potentially extremely high, espe-cially if the family could try to buy something thatthe other shops in the same village did not supply.396/591

      marginal return of increasing the size of the inventory a little was potentially extremely high

    4. The overall return on a business, on the otherhand, is the total revenue net of operating expenses(the costs of materials, any wages you pay to yourworkers, and so on).

      overall return on business (total revenue net of operating expenses)

    5. Compared to other ex-tremely poor households that were not selected toparticipate, the beneficiaries have more animals andother business assets; they earn more from livestockand other animals, but they also work longer hoursand earn more from working for others

      work longer hours but do better

    6. In particular, we went backto the story of Ben Sedan, who was convinced thathe had no use for more money. Fouad drew up aclearly feasible business plan for him. He could takea loan, build a stable, and buy four young cows.They would not need to graze in a field: They couldbe fed in the stable. Within eight months, he couldsell the cows for a hefty profit. Fouad was persuadedthat if someone explained this to him, Ben Sedanwould see the wisdom of this plan and take out aloan

      Ben Sedan rejected a microfinance plan, showing not all poor want the same things

    7. Muhammad Yunus, founder of the world-famousGrameen Bank, often describes the poor as naturalentrepreneurs. Combined with the late businessguru C. K. Prahalad’s exhortation to businessmen tofocus more on what he called the “bottom of thepyramid,” 1 the idea of the entrepreneurial poor ishelping to secure a space within the overall anti-poverty policy discourse where big business andhigh finance feel comfortable getting involved.

      Muhammad Yunus and CK Prahalad: the poor are just young entrepeneurs

    8. dawn the women went to the beach, where they col-lected wet sea sand. They then laid it evenly on thestreet before the real traffic began. When the carsstarted driving over the sand, the heat from theirwheels dried it. All they had to do then was occa-sionally to scrape off the top layer of sand, now dry.By nine or ten, they had a quantity of dry sand,which they brought back to the slum to sell in smallpackets made from discarded newspapers: The localwomen used the dry sand to scrub their dishes.This, the uncle reckoned, was true entrepreneur-ship: If you have very little, use your ingenuity tocreate something out of nothing

      enginuity, making something from nothing. In this case, using dry sand to sell to clean dishes

    9. The microfinance movement has demonstratedthat, despite the difficulties, it is possible to lend tothe poor. Although one may debate the extent towhich MFI loans transform the lives of the poor, thesimple fact that MFI lending has reached its currentscale is a remarkable achievement. There are veryfew other programs targeted at the poor that havemanaged to reach so many people. However, thestructure of the program, which is the source of itssuccess in lending to the poor, is such that we can-not count on it to be a stepping-stone for largerbusinesses to be created and financed.

      MFI is not usable for long term success

    10. Miao Lei, with a good degree and a reasonablebusiness model, had to gamble to survive. NarayanMurthy and Nandan Nilekani, despite their degreesfrom the ultra-prestigious Indian Institute of Tech-nology, could not get a loan to start the firm Infosysbecause the banker objected that the bank could seeno inventory to lend against. Infosys today is one ofthe largest software firms in the world. It is hard notto assume that there are a lot more people like thesethree, but who just couldn’t make it because theydidn’t get the right financing at the right time

      hard for larger businesses to start

    11. Microfinance gives itsclients every incentive to play it safe, so it is not wellsuited to discover who has an appetite for risk tak-ing.

      microfinance is not really for people looking to take big risks

    12. The necessary focus on repayment discipline im-plies that microfinance is not the natural or bestway to finance entrepreneurs who want to gobeyond micro-enterprises.

      microfinance is not the right fit for entrepeneurs who want to go beyond micro-enterprises

    13. This time, Spandana and Share, one of its competit-ors, were accused of being the reason a number offarmers had committed suicide. According to a newseries of articles in the press, loan officers hadpushed the clients to overborrow, then put unfairpressure on them to repay. The MFIs obviouslydenied the charges, but before anything could be re-solved, the district commissioner of Krishna (theadministrative head of the district) decreed that re-paying one’s loan to Spandana or Share was . . . il-legal.

      antagonism between local government and MFIs

    14. that microfinance is auseful financial product. But that apparently is notenough. Trapped by decades of overpromising,many of the leading players in the microfinanceworld have apparently decided they would ratherrely on the power of denial than take stock, regroup,and admit that microfinance is only one of the pos-sible arrows in the fight against poverty

      pedople had excessively high expectations with microfinance

    15. In our minds, mi-crocredit has earned its rightful place as one of thekey instruments in the fight against poverty

      microcredit did not help women or children empowerment, but did do the job

    16. People in the Spandana neighborhoods were morelikely to have started a business and more likely tohave purchased large durable goods, such as bi-cycles, refrigerators, or televisions. Households thatdid not start a new business were consuming morein these neighborhoods, but those who had started anew business were actually consuming less, tighten-ing their belts to make the most of the new oppor-tunity.

      Spandana data showed people were enthusiastic to learn

    17. All of these innovations contribute to reducingthe administrative costs of lending, which, as we ar-gued above, get blown up by the multiplier effectand make lending to the poor so very expensive.This is how most MFIs in South Asia manage tomake money by lending to the poor at interest ratesof around 25 percent per year,

      MFIs are better because they typicaly make it a week to repay a fixed amount

    18. From its modest beginnings with the BangladeshRehabilitation Assistance Committee (universallyknown as BRAC) and the Grameen Bank in themid-1970s in Bangladesh, microcredit is now aglobal phenomenon.

      BRAC+Grameen have made microcredit a global phenomenon

    19. he Indian branch of Citibank gotinto serious trouble when it was discovered that itwas using “goondas” (local hooligans) to threatenborrowers who did not repay vehicle loans. And thecourts are not really an option, either. In 1988, theLaw Commission of India reported that 40 percentof the cases for asset liquidation (of bankrupt bor-rowers) were more than eight years pending

      Formal banks cannot use the more coercive methods, so they need to have high interest

    20. Kabuliwala kills someone who was trying tocheat him. The same logic also explains why theMob in the United States was for many people the“lender of last resort.”

      Kabuliwala--lender of last resort, predator

    21. Thereport describes debt collectors in India making useof the old social prejudice against eunuchs to collectfrom long-standing defaulters. Because people be-lieve that seeing a eunuch’s genitals brings bad luck,the eunuchs were instructed to show up at the de-faulter’s house and threaten a “showing” if they con-tinued to be uncooperative

      eunichs to demand repayment

    22. To make matters worse, this creates what eco-nomists call a multiplier effect. When the interestrate goes up, the borrower has more reason to try tofind a way not to repay the loan. That means theborrower needs to be monitored and screened morecarefully, which adds to the cost of lending. Thispushes the interest rate up even further, which ne-cessitates more scrutiny, and so on.

      multiplier effect=positive feedback loop=more interest-->more attempts to avoid repayment

    23. The way lenders all over the world protect them-selves against the different forms of willful default isby asking for a down payment, some collateral, orwhat is sometimes called the promoter’s contribu-tion, which is the part of the firm’s capital thatcomes from the entrepreneur’s pocket. If the bor-rower defaults on the loan, the lender can punishher by seizing the collateral

      lending and collateral demands

    24. But second, the interest rates charged byinformal sources tend to be higher for the poor thanfor the less poor. The average interest rate from aninformal source drops by 0.4 percent per month foreach additional hectare of land owned by the persontaking out the loan

      for each additional hectare of land owned by a person taking out a loan, their interest rate decreases by 0.4%

    25. and only 6.4 percent from a formalsource.

      In Udaipur, only 6.4% of loans were from a formal bank

    26. According to Padmaja, the ragpicker ex-plained that the bank would not lend to someonelike her. She could have gotten a loan from amoneylender, but the rates would have been so highthat it would not have been worth it. In the end,Padmaja decided to give her a loan. The ragpickerreimbursed it faithfully and flourished. Soon after,people were lining up at Padmaja’s doorstep forloans, and she decided to quit her job to startSpandana. Thirteen years later, in July 2010,Spandana had 4.2 million loan clients, with an out-standing portfolio of 42 billion rupees.

      Spandana loans are lower interest and better overall to help people recover finances

    27. Padmaja Reddy

      microfinance to avoid making the poor deal with these high expenses

    28. This in-terest payment is 4.69 percent per day.1 To seewhat this means, try the following calculation: Ifyou borrowed 100 rupees ($5.10 USD PPP) todayand kept it until tomorrow, you would need to repay104.69 rupees. If you kept this amount a furthertwenty-four hours and repaid it the following day,you would need to repay 109.6 rupees. After thirtydays, you would owe almost 400 rupees, and after ayear, 1,842,459,409 rupees ($93.5 million USDPPP). So the equivalent of a $5 loan, if it goes unre-paid for a year, leaves a debt of nearly $100 million

      the idea of debt traps from high interest

    29. Children who are completely lost inthe regular school system (their test scores are waybehind those of other children when they enter

      charter schiools are good as a way to catch up some students

    30. This message of scaling down expectations, focus-ing on the core competencies, and using technologyto complement, or if necessary substitute for, teach-ers, does not sit well with some education experts

      future but controversial

    31. Despite the fact that they only got to play fortwo hours a week, the gains from this program interms of math scores were as large as those of someof the most successful education interventions thathave been tried in various contexts over the years,and this was true across the board—the strongestchildren did better, and so did the weakest children.This highlights what is particularly good about thecomputer as a learning tool: Each child is able to sethis or her own pace through the program. 4

      benefits of self-guided study

    32. A pro-gram in Kenya that offered a $20 USD PPP scholar-ship for the next year to girls who scored in the top15 percent on an exam not only got the girls to domuch better, but it also put pressure on the teachersto work harder (to help the girls), which meant thatboys did better, too, even though there was noscholarship for them. 42 I

      benefit of scholarship incentives

    33. allow children to learn at their own pace, and inparticular to make sure the children who are laggingbehind can focus on the basics.

      benefits of students learning at their own pace

    34. Infosys, one of India’s IT giants,has set up testing centers where people, includingthose without much formal qualification, can walkin and take a test that focuses on intelligence andanalytical skills rather than textbook learning.Those who do well get to become trainees, and suc-cessful trainees get a job.

      Raman boards and Infosys trying to incorproate non-traditional educational backgrounds

    35. It should now be clear why private schools do notdo better at educating the average child—their en-tire point is to prepare the best-performing childrenfor some difficult public exam that is the stepping-stone toward greater things, which requires power-ing ahead and covering a broad syllabus.

      private schools more prepare only the best for exams

    36. World Ban

      WB and caste as a significant variable in performance

    37. But this behavior creates a poverty trap even wherenone exists in the first place. If they give up, theywill never find out that perhaps the child could havemade it. And in contrast, families that assume thattheir children can make it, or families that don’twant to accept that a child of theirs will remain un-educated, which tend to be, for obvious historicalreasons, more elite families, end up confirmed intheir “high” hopes.

      confirmation bias and framing

    1. he effects ofthe treatment on schooling are large and striking; there are fewexamples of policies or interventions that result in a 0.20- to 0.35-year increase in schooling, much less interventions that are aspotentially inexpensive as this one.

      just information sharing

    2. This finding suggests a possible inefficiency andmay even a reflect a potential development trap, as the relativeskill composition demanded by the labor market is not transmit-ted to youths in the form of greater perceived returns, resultingin an undersupply of skilled labor, which in turn inhibits the de-velopment of domestic skill–intensive industries or the ability toattract foreign direct investment.

      undersupply of skilled labor since demand for advanced education is lower

    3. Overall, the effects for the least poor students are large andstriking. The magnitudes compare favorably with large-scale pro-grams implemented elsewhere, such as Mexico’s PROGRESA,which provided direct cash incentives to increase school atten-dance. 29 And many of these other programs are extremely expen-sive, 30 whereas in the present case, information could potentiallybe provided at low cost.

      effects fot eh least poor students are far more striking

    4. For the poorest households, the effect of the treatment is ex-tremely small and not statistically significant for all three mea-sures of schooling. This is despite the fact that in column (8),the treatment appears to have had a large effect on perceivedreturns to schooling for these students. By contrast, for youthsfrom wealthier (though still quite poor) households, the effectsare large, and statistically significant at the 10% level or bet-ter for all three education measures (though the effect for finishedsecondary is not statistically significant without the additional co-variates (Table A.6 in the Online Appendix), and only marginallysignificant with them).

      this implies that the poor cannot really act on the information they are aware of

    5. As noted above, within the standard human capital frame-work, demand is not always sufficient for schooling. For someyouths, even if they wanted to attend school, a combination ofcosts, low family income, and credit constraints will limit theeffectiveness of the intervention.

      constraints on school demand: 1. cost 2. low family income 3. credit constraints

    6. The table showsthat the treatment group was four percentage points (7%) morelikely to have returned to school the following year, though thedifference is only marginally statistically significant (p-value of.091). They also achieved on average 0.18 more years of schoolingover the next four years. Finally, the difference in the likelihood ofcompleting secondary school is positive, but small (two percentagepoints) and not statistically significant.

      these results are not statistically significant but can still be of practical interest

    7. Overall, these results are further confirmation thatsurvey measures of perceptions are useful predictors of schoolingoutcomes, supporting the conclusions of Kaufmann (2008) andAttanassio and Kaufmann (2008).

      survey measures are useful predictors of schooling outcomes

    8. The fact that students have such low perceived returns toschooling raises the possibility that providing information on thehigher measured returns may improve schooling.

      hypothesis of the paper

    9. The means here are lower than own expected earnings forboth levels of education, consistent with a general optimism bias

      general optimism bias

    10. Of course, these regressions may be plagued by omitted vari-ables bias (e.g., those with low perceived returns may attendlower-quality schools) or reverse causality (e.g., a “sour grapes”effect whereby those who want to go to school but are constrainedfrom doing so by poor grades or low income report low returns). Al-though we would not want to attach a strong causal interpretationto these results, they provide an initial impression that measuredperceptions do have some predictive value (though it should benoted that the perception measure alone can account for only1%–2% of the total variation in the various schooling outcomes

      regression risk of OVB since low percieved returns may be endemic to low quality schools

    11. The average householdincome is approximately RD$3,500 per month, and 38% of youthshave fathers who finished high school. At baseline, students ex-pect earnings at age 30–40 of RD$3,516 if they only finish primaryschool and RD$3,845 if they finish secondary school, both of whichare slightly greater on average than what they believe currentworkers aged 30–40 with those levels of education earn

      student expectations are slightly higher than what we expect them to earn

    12. ssign-ment of the treatment was done at the school level rather thanfor individual students within schools because students in thesame school are likely to communicate, which would contaminatethe control group.

      removing spill over

    13. The two sets of questions can therefore be used to deter-mine in part whether students’ perceptions differ from measuredreturns because (a) they have poor or inaccurate information onprevailing wages in the labor market (as captured by the secondset of questions), or (b) they have information or beliefs aboutthemselves (correct or incorrect) that influence what they expectearnings will be for them personally (as captured by the first setof questions).

      two possibilities for low attendance to secondary schooling a. misinformed b. making a decision based on personal belifs

    14. Overall, we were able to obtain follow-up informa-tion in the October 2001 survey directly from 93% of youths, with2% from relatives and 5% from neighbors. By the 2005 survey,this had changed to 89% from youths, 4% from relatives, and7% from neighbors. In all cases, we attempted to verify educa-tional attainment by contacting the school that students were re-ported to be attending or had attended.

      low attrition rates by also asking for local community members' input

    15. Using data from a panel survey of boys in the Dominican Re-public in the eighth grade, the last year of compulsory schoolingand the point at which most students terminate their education,we find that perceptions of the returns to secondary schooling areextremely low for most students, especially relative to returnsmeasured with earnings data. Although many factors may affector limit school attendance, such as poverty and credit constraints,these results raise the possibility that for at least some youths,school dropout may be the result of low demand due to low per-ceived returns

      low demand due to low perceived returns

    16. only about 25%–30% completesecondary school (Oficina Nacional de Estad ́ıstica, Rep ́ublica Do-minicana 2002).

      dr secodnary schooling is quite low

    17. Manski(1993), it is the returns perceived by students and/or their parentsthat will influence actual schooling decisions.

      Manski: importance of perceived returns to education

    18. Though many studies estimate these returns with earningsdata, it is the perceived returns that affect schooling decisions, and these percep-tions may be inaccurate.

      perceived returns to secondary education are low

    Annotators