- Apr 2023
-
Local file Local file
-
Third, committing to deliver basic incomes for along period of time could have effects that differ from the effects of shorter-term transfers them-selves. This is true for (at least) two reasons. First, the basic logic of intertemporal smoothingsuggests that recipients may be less likely to save a marginal dollar today if they expect to con-tinue receiving transfers far into the future. Second, the expectation of income support in thefuture could increase recipients’ tolerance for risk taking today in settings where they are poorlyinsured and close to subsistence
committing to delivering UBI for a long time beneicial since 1. people may be les likely to save if they expect to get money in the future 2. may make people more willing to tolerate risk
-
For example, Duflo (2000) finds that pension payments to grandmothersbut not grandfathers led to anthropometric gains for granddaughters in the same households inSouth Africa, while Akresh et al. (2016) find in Burkina Faso that, if anything, transfers to fathershad larger impacts on children’s health, while also yielding greater investment
Duflo (2000): pension payments to grandmothers led to gains for granddaughters in SA
-
Second, delivering UBI to each adult in a household (whichis what many basic income proposals contemplate) could have different effects from deliveringthe same amount of money to a single adult representative of the household (which is how mostexisting cash transfer programs function). If the unitary model of the household were correct, then,of course, this distinction would not matter, but there is ample evidence that many households arenonunitary in consequential ways (Chiappori & Donni 2009). Individualizing transfers could thushave important effects, both by changing who decides how those particular dollars are spent andby changing the outside options that each family member holds and thus their influence on variousother decisions.
it is important to consider each person an indviidual instead of allocating aid by household
-
Mechanically, broader coverage could change the average impact of cash transfers by changingthe identity of the average recipient. Generally speaking, existing programs have tended to targetthe poor or vulnerable—widows, the elderly, low-income parents, and so on. The average recipientof UBI would thus tend to be less poor and less vulnerable than the recipients of existing programs.To forecast how exactly this would affect program impacts, we could potentially adjust existinganalyses by reweighting each observation by an estimate of each household’s (inverse) propensityto be treated, in an effort to give equal weight to impacts on all sorts of people.
examining impacts on entire populations is important to understanding the effects of UBI
-
Second, evaluations have found a great diversity of positive impacts. For example, a partial listof outcomes affected in a positive way in one study or another, according to Bastagli et al. (2016),includes income, assets, savings, borrowing, total expenditure, food expenditure, dietary diversity,school attendance, test scores, cognitive development, use of health facilities, labor force partici-pation, child labor migration, domestic violence, women’s empowerment, marriage, fertility, anduse of contraception
evaluations of UBI have been overwhelmingly positive. A partial list of outcomes: income, assets, savings, female wmpoerment, use of contraception, cognitive development
-
First, evaluations generally have not found the negative impacts that many feared. Reviewingevidence on temptation goods, Evans & Popova (2017) find that transfers had on average reducedexpenditure on temptation goods by 0.18 standard deviations. In other words, far from blowingtheir transfers on alcohol and tobacco, recipients appear to drink and smoke less
It appears that UBI motivates people to spend less on temptation goods by about 0.18 standard deviations
-
552 million people living in the developing world who receive some form of cashtransfer from their government
2018: 552 million people living in the developing world recieve some form of cash transfer from their government
-
UBI in some other potentiallyconsequential way. We emphasize two dimensions in particular. First, existing transfers have notbeen universal but rather targeted, both to subsets of households (through means testing, ordeals,conditions, etc.) and to specific adults within those households (often the female head). Second,existing transfers typically last for relatively short time periods, as opposed to the long-termcommitment envisioned by UBI advocates. Both of these differences could lead to importantdifferences in impacts.
issues with existing UBI experiments in developing economics 1. existing transfers have not been universal, but very targeted toward only adults 2. short time horizon
-
one fortwo years in nine villages in the Indian state of Madhya Pradesh, one in two villages in Namibia,and Iran’s nation-wide cash transfer introduced in 2011 to offset the withdrawal of food andfuel subsidies.
three UBI studies in the developing world -Madhya Pradesh -Namibia -Iran
-
echnocratsmight need to be convinced to hand over money to the poor that they otherwise could have used todesign and implement projects in their own areas of expertise and motivation—projects designedto achieve narrower goals for health, education, nutrition, and so on. Taxpaying voters would needto be convinced to support handouts despite commonly held concerns that they would reducerecipients’ own initiative or trigger self-harmful behaviors such as drinking or drug use.
funding UBI requires convincing both technocrats and taxpaying voters that this project will work for their ultimate goals, which could be a tough sell
-
. Clearly, funding anything close to UBI would require a substantialshare of available resources. Some countries undoubtedly have scope to raise additional revenue,but in general, LICs raise substantially less revenue as a share of GDP than wealthier ones, likelybecause their capacity to do so is limited (Gordon & Li 2009)
funding anything close to UBI requires a substantial share of available resources, and LICs raise substantially less revenue as a share of GDP than wealthier ones which means their capacity is limited
-
In the developing world, large-scale basic income schemes could plausibly be financed from(some combination of ) repurposed foreign aid, repurposed domestic tax revenue, or new taxrevenue—although they would place serious demands on any of these sources.
Large scale basic income schemes can be financed from -repurposed foreign aid -domestic tax revenue -new tax revenue
-
The net impact of the policy is then the sum of effects on net recipients andnet payers.
net impact of cash transfers=sum of effects on net recipients + net payers
-
. UBImight make sense because it will usually help a bit and will never entirely miss the mark. Moreover,of course, the opportunity cost of basic income as a growth intervention is low, since the bulk ofthe fiscal outlay is simply a progressive transfer
opportunity cost of basic income as a growth intervention is low isnce the bulk of the fiscal outlay is simply a progressive transfer instead of complex forms of aid
-
For any particular constraint, there is a plausible argument, and typically some evidence, that UBIcould help relax it.
to examine how UBI might affect the growth of income from other sources, we draw on literature to look at both financial and psychological constraints on poor people and how UBI may relax those concerns
-
This review, then, examines what we know and what we do not about these three issues
this paper takes on what we know and don't know about income-based development solutions
-
s a result,while we know that, in some countries, the private sector actually provides quality comparableto the public sector at a lower cost, this may not be true elsewhere.
in some courtries, private sector provides quality comparable to the public sector at a lower cost
-
Even if basic income is the best solution for some people, it is not obvious that it is universallybest. A targeted basic income could be a better use of scarce resources. This in turn depends onthe effectiveness of targeting
if you accept raising incomes is a goal and that a basic income tautologically achieves it, you don't need to support UBI
-
The reality, however, is that much of the spending on development is on issues like nutrition,health, and education, which may or may not be the priorities of the people that it is intended tohelp.
other more direct forms of aid do not assist people in the same way as income sine it may not match the priorities people have
-
e could argue that we do not. One of the central goals of development economics has been tounderstand how to raise the incomes of people who are poor. A sustainable program for universalbasic income (UBI) does that by definition.
Author believes universal basic income by definition raises incomes of the poor and that a central goal of development econ is to raise the incomes of the poor, linking UBI to be equivalent to the ultimate purpose of development
-
-
-
wever, it is worth noting that theeffects estimated in this paper may be larger than what wouldbe expected if cable were introduced more widely. Although wehave argued that preexisting trends in attitudes do not drive theresults, we cannot rule out the possibility that television is intro-duced first into areas that have the biggest potential for change;those that are receptive to television may also be receptive tochanging their gender attit
could be an issue of over-estimation
-
lower. Nevertheless, given the magnitudeof the effects estimated here, even much smaller effects could havesignificant impacts in
ok
-
n. However, one plausible mechanism is that television eposes rural households to urban lifestyles, values, and behaviothat are radically different from their own and that householdsbegin to adopt or emulate some of these, as suggested by maanthropological and ethnographic studies of te
idea that tv promotes urbanization
-
improves the status of women: women report lower acceptabilitof spousal abuse, lower son preference, more autonomy, and lowfertili
cable 1. improves the status of women 2. lower acceptability of spusal abuse 3. more autonomy 4. lower fertility 5. increase in school enrollment
-
Taken together, the DISE and SARI data suggest that cableleads to increased school enrollment for younger children. Giventhe large literature showing that increases in women's status anddecision-making authority are associated with gains in children'soutcomes, it is certainly plausible that the schooling results arerelated to the improvements in women's status, such as partici-pation in household decision making, documen
women and children as both re-enforcing one another via the introduction of cable
-
ollment. For the fixedcohort ages 6-7, the effect is large, with additional years increas-ing enrollment by 5%. For children ages 6-10, the effect is smaller,between 1% and 2%, but still statistically significant. Finally, con-sistent with the SARI data, we see no effect for the o
more relevant on younger kids vis a vis enrollment
-
e, regressing log enrollment on whether the village has cableand years of cable access. To account for possible serial correla-tion, we use the Prais-Winston estimator. The controls includeelectrification (inferred from whether the school has electricity),population,23 and distance to the neare
regressing log enrollment on whether the village has cable and the year of cable access
-
One other challenge is that our village survey only reportedthe year the village got cable, not the month. This makes it diffi-cult to match with precision the timing of cable introduction andschool enrollment. For example, villages that received cable in2002 may have added it in August, when it was already too lateto influence the decision on whether to enroll a child in the 2002-2003 academic year, because the school year begins in early Juneand late enrollment is generally not permitted. This suggests thatthe effects of cable on enrollment in many cases may not show upuntil at earliest the academic year starting in the calendar yearafter cable is introdu
challenge of perfect time alignment
-
, shows less clear results and, in particular, does not appear todemonstrate any "on-introduction" impact of cable: moving from2001 to 2002 in the 2002 adopters or 2002 to 2003 in the 2003adopters does not appear to increase enrollment. However, thereis a large increase between 2002 and 2003 for the 2002 adopters,again perhaps pointing to a delayed effect. Although the resultsfor women's status suggests immediate on-introduction effects, itis possible that any effects on education could take longer, forexample, because plans for education must be made further inadvance and money must be saved for fees and o
boys show less clear results than women, who ahve an "on-introduction" effect
-
here y^ is a full set of individual fixed effects, 8t is a full setof year dummies, and the other controls, Xivt, include householdincome and a quadratic i
definitions for variables
-
ent. In the villages that do not changecable status, enrollment is either flat or slightly decreasing overthe sample period. For those that get cable in 2002, enrollmentincreases between 2001 and 2002, and then further increases be-tween 2002 and 2003, suggesting some increasing impact overtime
increases in enrollment
-
n other words, it does not seem that there are changes in the out-comes that anticipate getting cable. Note that not only are thesecoefficients not statistically significant, but the point estimatesare extremely small, and in most cases statistically significantlydifferent from the effect of getting cable this year - so we can rejectthat any changes observed after cable is introduced are simply thecontinuation of preexistin
we can disprove that any changes observed after cable is introduced are simply the continuation of pre-existing trends
-
Cable Access and Female Au
cable access as it relates to female autonomy
-
This figure shows son preference (equal to 1 if the respondent reports wantinga son for the next child) from the SARI data, broken down by villages that alwayshave had cable, those that got cable for the first time in 2002, those that got it forthe first time in 2003, and those that never have had cable. The sample is onlyindividuals who report wanting more c
figure 3 cable access as it relates to son prerference
-
nd 2003. This graph sug-gests a strong connection between cable availability and televisionviewership, with a near doubling in bp
there is a strong link between cable access and television viewership
-
Cable Access and Television
intro of cable access usually will spike viewership then decline a little bit
-
es by these factors, we also include in the regressionsinteractions between a year indicator and state dummies, income,education, age and age-squared, village population density, elec-trification status, and distance to neares
interaction terms
-
e. Our identifying assumption is thatvillages that added cable would not otherwise have changed dif-ferently than those villages that did not add
assumption: villages that added cable would not otherwise have changed differently than villages that did not add cable. Counterfactual idea
-
ur basic empirical strategy is to compare changes in ourmeasures of women's status for villages that add cable over thecourse of the panel relative to those that do not. We run individual-level fixed-effects regressions of each outcome on cable availability(measured at the village level). Denote the outcome for individuali in village v in year t as stvt and the measure of cable access ascvt. The primary regression estima
compare changes in women's status for villages that add cable over the course of the panel relative to those that do not. Running individual-level fixed effects regressions of each outcome on cable availability measurred at the village level
-
Panel B of Table II reports summary statistics for thesemeasures. For the decision-making variables, we condense theresponses to binary indicators for whether the woman partici-pates in the decision (either decides on her own or decides jointlywith others in the household). Overall, slightly more than half ofwomen participate in each of the decisions. There is some overlapin these variables, though not as much as might be suggested bythe similarity of their means; about 20% of women do not par-ticipate in any of the decisions, 25% participate in one, 27% intwo, and 29% in three. About one-half of women report needingpermission to go to the market and two-thirds need permissionto visit family or friends.9 By contrast, nearly three-quarters ofwomen are allowed to keep money set aside to spend as they wish.However, by most measures, women's autonomy overall is quitelo
panel B shows that autonomy is overall quite low
-
Summary statistics for these two measures are in Panel B ofTable II. Over 60% of women feel that it is acceptable for a husbandto beat his wife under at least one of the six situations listed.On average, women report 1.6 situations in which it is consideredacceptable. Women are most likely to believe beating is acceptableif a wife neglects her children, goes out without permission, ordoes not show respect toward her husband. Perhaps surprisingly,being unfaithful is reported as valid justification for violence byslightly fewer women. In terms of son preference, 55% of womenwho want another child prefer that child to
60% of women feel it is acceptable for a husband to beat his wife in at least one of the six situations, avg of 1.6, and 55% of women had son preference
-
The outcome measure we use is the number of situations in whichthe woman reports that beating is accepta
analyzing prevalence of resposne here for the beating question
-
ll women in the sample households ages fifteen and olderwere interviewed (no men were interviewed).
all women in sample households 15+ were interviewed, no men interviewed
-
ur primary data set is SARI, a panel survey of 2,700 house-holds, each containing a person age fifty or older, conducted2001, 2002, and 2003 in four states (Bihar, Goa, Haryana, anTamil Nadu) and the capital, Delhi. The sample was selected itwo stages: in the first stage, 180 villages were selected at randomfrom district lists (40 villages in Bihar, Haryana, and Tamil Nadu35 in Delhi; and 25 in Goa), and in the second stage, 15 householdwere chosen within each village through random sampling basedon registration lists. Other than Delhi, the survey was confinedrural areas. Attrition over the panel was low, with just 108 (4%of the original households dropping out by t
panel data is SARI, a panel survey of 2,700 households in 2001, 2002, and 2003 in four states. Sample was selected in 2 stages, low attrition
-
. Note, however, that the R2 valuesin the regressions in Table I are small, indicating that much ofthe variation in cable access remains unexplai
much of the variation in cable access remains unexplained
-
These quantitative results are supportive of the qualitativeevidence from the interviews and suggest the importance of con-trolling for these determinants of cable access in our ana
weaving together qualitative and quantitative data to be mutually re-inforcing
-
anel B showsmultivariate regressions with these variables and, in column (4),includes state fixed effects to capture the fact that access variessignificantly across states. The broad patterns remain the same.In these data, there is some evidence of a role for income as adeterminant of cable access, suggesting it may be important tocontrol for it even though it was not explicitly mentioned by cableoperator
need to control for income shown with a multivariate regression and how state fixed effects are important. Evidence of a role for income as a determinant for cable access
-
8 (column (2)).tors, villages thatoverall
villages that are remote get cable later
-
The cable operator data can be used to examine the deter-minants of cable access more quantitatively by merging villageswith administrative data from an education database (again, de-scribed in more detail in Section V). Doing so allows us to ex-amine the village-level relationship between cable access and thecorrelates suggested above: distance to a town, population, andelectrification
examining village-level relationships between cable access and the correlates of: distance to a town, population, and electrification
-
n moving to a more quantitative analysis of the impacts ofcable, we must recognize that variation in access is certainly non-random. Therefore, understanding the determinants of the timingand placement of cable is important for our ability to attributechanges in women's status to the introduction of ca
a challenge in this study is that the introduction of cable is far from random, which means there need to be controls for placement of cable
-
nt. Another woman reports that because of tele-vision, men and women are able to "open up a lot more" (Scrase2002). Johnson (2001) quotes a number of respondents describingchanges in gender roles as a result of television. One man notes,"Since TV has come to our village, women are doing less workthan before. They only want to watch TV. So we [men] have to domore work. Many times I help my wife clean the h
idea of TV and cable as something that re-arranges the domestic space.
-
lso), a show based aroundthe life of a wealthy industrial family in the large city of Mumbai.As can be seen from the title, the main themes and plots of theshow revolve around issues of family and g
issue of family and gender are covered in these cable shows
-
rly 1990s. In the five yearsfrom 2001 to 2006, about 30 million households, representing ap-proximately 150 million individuals, added c
2001-2006: 150 million Indians are more exposed to cable TV
-
ess so. In fact, the government of TamilNadu has recently begun a program to provide free color tele-visions to 7.5 million households with the goal of ensuring thatevery household has one by
Tamil Nadu is adding a program to provide free color teelvisions to 7.5 million households with the goal of ensuring everyone has a household by 2011
-
rollment. Using both ourhousehold panel data and administrative data for roughly 1,000villages in the state of Tamil Nadu, we provide evidence that theintroduction of cable increases school enrollment for younger chil-dr
using 1,000 villages in the state of tramil nadu and household panel data shows intro of cable also promtes school enrollment
-
tus. We argue that this does not appearto be the case, first showing visually that there are no preexist-ing differential trends in women's status for villages that do anddo not add cable, and that the timing of changes in outcomes isclosely aligned with the introduction of cable; and second, that theoutcomes are not correlated with future cable access.
adressing the central empirical concern that the trends in variables like income or modernity affect both cable access and women's status (so confounding variables). They address this by showing that there are not any differential trends in women's status for villages that do and do not add cable. Plus timing is closely aligned with the introduction of cable
-
sing these data, we find that cable television has large ef-fects on women's status. After cable is introduced to a village, thereare significant changes in gender attitudes: women are less likelyto report that it is acceptable for a husband to beat his wife, andless likely to express a preference for sons. Behaviors tradition-ally associated with women's status also change: women reportincreased autonomy (e.g., the ability to go out without permissionand to participate in household decision making) and lower fertil-ity
reports that women generally remove stereotypes that inhibit their status
-
The primary analysis relies on a three-year panel data setcovering women in five Indian states between 2001 and 2003.These years represent a time of rapid growth in rural cable ac-cess. During the panel, cable television was newly introduced in21 of the 180 sample villa
the primary analysis is a three-year panel data set covering women in 5 Indian states between 2001 and 2003. These years are a time of rapid growth in rural cable access, during the panel cable television was newly introduced in 21/180 sample villages
-
men. Although issues of gender equality are im-portant throughout the world, they are particularly salient inIndia. Sen (1992) argued that there were 41 million "missingwomen" in India - women and girls who died prematurely dueto mistreatment - resulting in a dramatically male-biased popu-latio
television as a way to resolve the missing women dilemma
-
. Most popular cable programming features urban settingswhere lifestyles differ in prominent and salient ways from those inrural areas. For example, many characters on popular soap operashave more education, marry later, and have smaller families, allthings rarely found in rural areas; and many female characterswork outside the home, sometimes as professionals, running busi-nesses or in other positions of auth
What is presented on popular cable programing is a more ubranized and developed series of behaviors
-
ndia has not been left out of the cable and satellite revolution:a recent survey finds that 112 million households in India owna television, with 61% of those homes having cable or satelliteservice (National Readership Studies Council 2006). This figurerepresents a doubling in cable access in just five years from aprevious survey. The survey finds that in some states, the changehas been even more dramatic; in the span of just ten to fifteenyears since it first became available, cable or satellite penetrationhas reached an astonishing 60% in states such as Tamil Nadu,even though the average income is below the World Bank povertyline of two dollars per person per
massive penetration of television, 61% of homes in India have a cable or sattelite service
-
Several studies have demonstrated that the information andexposure provided by television can influence a wide range ofattitudes and behavior. Gentzkow and Shapiro (2004) find thattelevision viewership in the Muslim world affects attitudes to-ward the West, and DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) show largeeffects of the Fox News Channel on voting patterns in the UnitedStates. In the developing world, Olken (2006) shows that televi-sion decreases participation in social organizations in Indonesia,and Chong, Duryea, and La Ferrara (2007) find that exposure tosoap operas in Brazil reduces f
existing literature La Ferrara-Brazil Olken in Indonesia
-
We argue that the results are not driven by preexisting diffe
these trends are not driven by pre-existing differential trends.
-
. Using a three-year, individual-level panel data set, we find that the intro-duction of cable television is associated with significant decreases in the reportedacceptability of domestic violence toward women and son preference, as well asincreases in women's autonomy and decrease
three-year individual panel data set that finds 1. introduction of cable television in associated with significant decreases in the reported acceptability of domestic violence toward women and son prefernece 2. increases in women's autonomy and decreases in fertilitty
-
nd behaviors. This paperexplores the effect of the introduction of cable television on women's status in ruralIndi
the paper explores the effect of the introduction of cable television on women's status in rural India.
-
. These media sources expose viewers to new information about the outsideworld and other ways of life, which may affect attitudes a
This paper is interesting in how media exposure can present information about the outside world to people in the devleoping world
-
-
Local file Local file
-
We document an important consequence of bride price, a paymentmade by the groom to the bride’s family at marriage. Revisiting Indone-sia’s school construction program, we find that among ethnic groups with-out the custom, it had no effect on girls’ schooling. Among ethnic groupswith the custom, it had large positive effects.
education raises price of dowry
-
-
Local file Local file
-
From a policy perspective, our estimates suggest that expanding the hiring of female teachers- both at the margin of the current patterns of hiring (assuming that the marginal female teacherhired has the same characteristics as the average female teacher), and also when holding othercharacteristics constant, would improve overall learning outcomes and be especially useful as atool for bridging gender gaps in learning trajectories over time
overall summary
-
This result is interesting because the rhetoric ofhiring female teachers is often based on the belief that having female teachers increases thesafety and comfort of girls in school, and that their presence therefore encourages girls to attendschool. Our results suggest however, that the mechanism for the positive impact of a gendermatch on test scores is less likely to be due to effects on the extensive margin of schoolparticipation, but more due to the increased effectiveness of classroom transactions betweenteachers and students.
more about the effectivity of classroom transactions
-
Since all test scores are normalized by grade and subject, theestimated coefficients can be directly interpreted as the correlation between the covariate andannual gains in normalized test scores
all scores normalized by grade and subject so the coefficients can be directly unsterood as the correlation between x and the fains in test scores
-
presents summary statistics for the teachers in our analysis. Femaleteachers comprise 46% of the total teacher body, but are less experienced, less likely to havecompleted high school or a masters degree, and less likely to hold a head-teacher position. Notsurprisingly, their mean salaries are also lower. They also comprise a much greater share of thecontract teacher work-force than that of regular civil-service teachers. Since teachercharacteristics vary systematically by gender, we will report our key results on the impact ofmatching teacher and student gender, both with and without controls for these additional teachercharacteristics
need for controls for additional teacher characteristics since female teachers have lower wages
-
However, this attrition over time is not a first-order concern forthis paper because it is highly unlikely that the additional 3% of female students who appear forthe test each year (relative to boys) would have test scores that are differentially affected byhaving a female teacher
issue of attrition is adressed here, maybe ask
-
Together, these results suggest that the overall gains from hiring female teachers comemainly from improving mean math test scores relative to male teachers (positive for girls, noeffect for boys) than from language (positive for girls, negative for boys, and no overall effect)
teaching more impacts math than language
-
The result above is a difference-in-difference estimate that compares the relative advantageof female teachers in teaching girls rather than boys with the relative disadvantage of maleteachers in teaching girls rather than boys, and is symmetric by construction
diff-in-diff utility
-
Girls have significantly higher test scores inlanguage and equal test scores in math relative to boys at the end of grade one, but score almoston par with boys in language and significantly worse in math by the end of grade five. Theseresults are consistent with evidence of gender gaps in test scores (particularly in math)documented in both high and low income countries (Fryer and Levitt 2010, Bharadwaj et al.2012), and suggest that the growing gender gaps documented at later ages in both these papersprobably reflect a cumulative effect of a trend that starts as early as primary schoo
gender gaps redlect a cumulative trend from primary school that girls mostly lose an early lead
-
he dataset features annual longitudinal data on student learning measuredthrough independent assessments of learning conducted over five years across a representativesample of 500 rural schools and over 90,000 students in the Indian state of Andhra Pradesh
research setting
-
(6) Finally, the increasing probability of having a male teacher inhigher grades can account for around 10-20% of the negative trend we find in girls' test scores as theymove to higher grades.
the probability of a male teacher can only account for 10-20% of the reason for why girls' tests scores have a negative trend
-
(5) We find no effect of having a same-genderteacher on student attendance, suggesting that the mechanism for the impact on learning outcomesis not on the extensive margin of increased school participation, but on the intensive margin of moreeffective classroom interactions;
no effect of same-gender teaching on students' efforts to attend class
-
(4) The overall gainsfrom having a female teacher are mainly attributable to their greater effectiveness at improving mathtest scores than male teachers (especially for girls);
women help girls with math especially
-
(3) However, female teachers are more effective overall,resulting in girls' test scores improving by an additional 0.036 in years when they are taught by a femaleteacher, with no adverse effects on boys when they are taught by female teachers;
female teachers more effective
-
We finda small but significant negative trend in girls' test scores in both math (0.02 /year) and language (0.01 /year)as they progress through the public primary school system; (2) Using five years of panel data, school-gradeand student gender by grade fixed effects, we find that both male and female teachers are more effectiveat teaching students of their own gender;
professors teach their own gender better than opposite
-
Recruiting female teachers is frequently suggested as a policy option for improving girls' educationoutcomes in developing countries, but there is surprisingly little evidence on the effectiveness of sucha policy. We study gender gaps in learning outcomes, and the effectiveness of female teachers in reducingthese gaps using a large, representative, annual panel data set on learning outcomes in rural publicschools in the Indian state of Andhra Pradesh.
using panel data
-
-
warwick.ac.uk warwick.ac.uk
-
But there is considerable slack to im-prove institutions and policy at the margin
"policy at the margin"
-
The focus on thebroad INSTITUTIONS as a necessary and sufficientcondition for anything good to happen is somewhatmisplaced.
BD prefer more local interests
-
This result suggests that a credible message canconvince the voters to vote in favor of general-in-terest policies. Once the trust is there, the individualpolitician’s incentives also change. He can start tofeel that if he does something good he will be appre-ciated and reelected.
credible messages can convince the voters to vote in favor of general-interest-policies Wantchekon
-
Invillages that had never had reserved seats for wo-men, and therefore had no experience of a womanleader, men who heard the “male” speech gave high-er approval ratings than those who heard the “fe-male” speech. On the other hand, in villages thathad been reserved for women before, men tended tolike the “female” speech better.
evidence of panchiyat random gender leadership success
-
The nurses’ workload was based on an ideologythat wants to see nurses as dedicated social workers,designed in ignorance of the conditions on theground, that lives on, mostly just on paper, becaus
example w nurses
-
This is whatwe call, for short, the “three Is” problem: ideology,ignorance, inertia. This problem plagues many ef-forts to supposedly help the poor
policy to help the poor can suffer from the three Is 1. ignorance 2. inertia 3. ideology
-
In our visits to the village, we couldhardly find anyone to acknowledge that the nurseswere absen
monitoring totally backfired.
-
To see whether this new policy made a difference,we sent independent survey researchers to recordabsence both in the centers that Seva Mandir wasmonitoring and in the other centers (where thesame rules applied in principle but where there wasno monitoring). 34 Initially, everything went accord-ing to plan. Nurse attendance, which was around 30percent before the launch of the program, jumpedto 60 percent by August 2006 in centers where SevaMandir was monitoring, but it remained unchangedelsewhere.
importance of monitoring, but this trend eroded over time
-
The risk of corruption and neglect is thus endem-ic in any government, but it is likely to be moresevere in three circumstances:
corruption more likely to be severe when: 1. government is trying to get people to do things whose value they don't appreciate 2. people are getting something worth a lot more than that they are paying for it 3. underpaying government workers
-
Governments exist toa large extent to solve problems that markets cannotsolve—we have already seen that in many instancesgovernment intervention is necessary preciselywhen, for some reason, the free market cannot dothe job.
governments exist to solve problems market cannot, so ofc i tis hard to craft policies
-
hepolicy, as we have reported, led to an increase ineducation and, for the generations that benefitedfrom this schooling, an increase in wages. The edu-cation expansion was accompanied by a massiveprogram promoting better nutritional practices forchildren, in part by training 1 million village volun-teers who were supposed to bring the message totheir villages.
Suharto's education program (good policy in a negative regime)
-
The import-ant lesson is to take advantage of whatever slackthere is
in dev, take advantage of whatever slack there is
-
Political economy is the view (embraced, as we haveseen, by a number of development scholars) thatpolitics has primacy over economics: Institutionsdefine and limit the scope of economic policy
political economy=institutions define and limit the scope of economic policy
-
In the “clientelist” villages, thespeech stressed the ethnic origin of the candidateand promised to bring schools and hospitals to theregion and government jobs to his people. In the“national unity” villages, the same candidate prom-ised to work for a national reform of the health andeducation sector and to work for peace among allthe ethnic groups of Benin. The villages were ran-domly chosen to get different speeches, but all ofthem were in the candidate’s political stronghold.The clientelist speech was a clear winner: On aver-age, the clientelist candidate got 80 percent of thevotes, as opposed to 70 percent in the national unityvillages.
Clientalistic policies often will appeal more on a local level
-
Further studies elsewhere in India have made itclear that women leaders almost always make a dif-ference. Furthermore, over time, women also ap-pear to be doing more than men with the same lim-ited budget and are reported to be less inclined totake bribes.
women have different priorities
-
India’s system of village government, or grampanchayat (the GP, or village council), has such re-strictions.
GP ministry in India forces some more representation for minorities
-
The so-called Community Driven Development pro-jects, in which the communities choose and managecollective projects, are quite the rage in post-conflictenvironments like those in Sierra Leone, Rwanda,Liberia, and Indonesia
Community-Driven developmernt (in practice the implementation matters a lot and there are a lot of steps for it to go wrong
-
In particular, there was an increase inpublic health expenditures and a reduction in thenumber of low-birth-weight babies among less edu-cated mothers. A seemingly minor technical fix, in-volving no major political battle, changed the way inwhich the voice of the poor was taken into accountin Brazil’s political process
technical fixes can really substantially improve outcomes
-
of a large num-ber of voters. In the average election, almost 25 per-cent of the votes were invalid and not counted. Inthe late 1990s, electronic voting was introduced, atfirst in the largest municipalities, and then in all ofthem
Study from Fujiwara
-
no guarantee that good INSTITUTIONSnecessarily work well in practice.
no gaurantee that good institutions will work well in practce
-
Once thisis done, it will be possible, for example, to requirepeople to scan their fingerprints to take delivery ofany subsidized grains from the government fair-price shops. This will make it much harder for theshop owners to sell off the grains at market pricesand claim that they have sold to the poor.
technical fix=contribute to making life better for the poor through standardizing aid and prevent exploitation
-
Indian police stations are evaluated on the basis ofthe number of unsolved cases, that is, the more un-resolved cases, the worse the evaluation. Therefore,an easy way to get better evaluations is to register asfew cases as possible. In our first set of decoy visits,only 40 percent of the cases actually got to the pointwhere the police were willing to register them (atwhich point our decoys were required to reveal thatit was just a test). It is therefore no surprise that thepoor rarely attempt to report any petty crimes to thepolice.The police in India represent a near-perfect ex-ample of a persistent colonial institution. Despitethe fact that they were originally designed to protectthe interests of the colonists, there was no attemptto reform the Indian police after Independence
no attempt to reform police has happened in India, cops are unwilling to assist
-
Yet, Olkenshowed that the threat of audits reduced the theft ofwages and materials by one-third, compared to thevillages where audits were not conducted (the vil-lages where audits were conducted were randomlyselected).
Olken: threat of audits can compel compliance
-
After a villagestarts holding elections, the village chiefs are morelikely to relax unpopular central policies, such asthe one-child policy.
elections lead to the relaxing of unpopular policies
-
donesiaunder Suharto, Brazil during the military dictator-ship, and Mexico under the Institutional Revolu-tionary Party (PRI)
local
-
CHANGES AT THE MARGIN
changes at the margin
-
are very persistent, and there may be no naturalprocess to eliminate them.
A and R: may be no natural process to eliminate bad institutions
-
Easterly also wantsgovernments to stop pushing education and healthcare on an indifferent populace but rather allowthem the freedom to find ways to get themselveseducated and healthy, through their own collectiveaction
Easterly wants less emphasis on education and health care
-
Easterly has one piece of ex-pert advice—freedom.
Easterly values freedom
-
William Easterly. 12 The centralproblem, he rightly points out, is that it is easier totake over a country than to know how to make it runwell.
William Easterly, pro hands=off development
-
Paul Collier, an OxfordUniversity professor and former World Bank eco-nomist, argues that there are sixty “basket case”countries (think Chad, Congo, and so forth) inwhich about 1 billion people live. 11 These countriesare stuck in a vicious circle of bad economic and badpolitical institutions, and it is the duty of theWestern world to get them out, if necessary throughmilitary interventions.
Paul Collier, pro British support / european support for democratization. White man's burden 2,0
-
If you can-not run your country, subcontract it to someonewho can. 10 Still, running an entire country may bedifficult. So he proposes starting with cities, smallenough to be manageable but large enough to makea difference. Inspired by the example of Hong Kong,developed with great success by the British and thenhanded back to China, he developed the concept of“charter cities.” Countries would hand over anempty strip of territory to a foreign power, whowould then take the responsibility for developing anew city with good institutions
"charter cities"-Paul Romer
-
incumbent on the rich countries of the world to helpthem get better institutions, by force, if need be. Inthe other view, any attempt at manipulating institu-tions or policies from the top down is doomed tofail, and changes can only come from within
two groups: pro-interventionist for development and the other believing it is useless
-
The ex-amples they emphasize are the Glorious Revolutionin England and the French Revolution.
A and R think it's possible to overcome bad institutions (English and French revolutions)
-
were individually responsible for their own taxes:These regions developed more cooperative and ho-rizontal social relationships.
british india and colonialism w Abhit and Iyer 1. zamandari system=local landlord gets to collect taxes (inneficient) rayatwari=farmers individually responsible, which creates more cooperation
-
“iron law of oligarchy.”
iron law of oligarchy=bad institutions perpetuate bad institutions
-
Acemoglu andRobinson define institutions as follows: “Economicinstitutions shape economic incentives, the incent-ives to become educated, to save and invest, to in-novate and adopt new technologies, and so on.Political institutions determine the ability of citizensto control politicians.
economic institutions=shape ecnomic incentives (education, save, invest, innovate) political institutions=ability for citizens to control politicians
-
Corruption, or the simple dereliction of duty, cre-ates massive inefficiencies. If teachers or nurses donot come to work, no education or health policy canreally be implemented. If truck drivers can pay asmall bribe to drive massively overloaded trucks,billions of dollars will be wasted in building roadsthat will be destroyed under their wheels.
corruption creates massive inefficiencies
-
If rural school headmasters could fightcorruption, perhaps it is not necessary to wait forthe overthrow of the government or the profoundtransformation of society before better policies canbe implemented. Careful thinking and rigorousevaluations can help us design systems to keep cor-ruption and inefficiency in check. We are not“lowering our ambitions”: Incremental progress andthe accumulation of these small changes, we be-lieve, can sometimes end in a quiet revolution
incremental progress and the accumulation of these small changes can create a quiet revolution
-
However, there was an interesting coda to Rein-ikka and Svensson’s story. When their results werereleased in Uganda, there was something of an up-roar, with the result that the Ministry of Financestarted giving the main national newspapers (andtheir local-language editions) month-by-month in-formation about how much money had been sent tothe districts for the schools. By 2001, when Rein-ikka and Svensson repeated their school survey,they found the schools were getting, on average, 80percent of the discretionary money that they wereentitled to.
Reinikka and Svenson's study was repeated a few years later and now 8- percent of discretionary money was allocated to the schools, which implies that accountability and transparency work
-
Jeffrey Sachs sees corrup-tion, perhaps not surprisingly, as a poverty trap:Poverty causes corruption, and corruption causespoverty.
Poverty trap and Jeffrey Sachs
-
There is no point to figuringout the best way to spend a dollar on schools, if 87cents will never reach the school anyway. It follows(or so it is assumed) that “big questions” require“big answers”—social revolutions, such as a trans-ition to effective democracy
institutionalist view, believes that there is no point in micro solutions, better to look at bigger questions/answers like transitions to democracy
-
It is to sort out the political process. If
institutionalist view=right political process=economic development
-
William Easterly, for one, criticized ran-domized control trials (RCTs) on his blog in theseterms: “RCTs are infeasible for many of the bigquestions in development, like the economy-wideeffects of good institutions or good macroeconomicpolicies.” Then, he concluded that “embracing RCTshas led development researchers to lower their am-bitions.” 3
easterly critiques RCT by thinking it makes development econ less ambitious
-
The answer they got was noth-ing short of stunning: Only 13 percent of the fundsever reached the schools. More than half the schoolsgot nothing at all. Inquiries suggested that a lot ofthe money most likely ended up in the pockets ofdistrict officials
money from these student grants, only 13% actually went to schools
-
In 1996, Ritva Reinikka andJakob Svensson
Reinikka and Svensson study on how much actual money went to the Uganda schools
-
Unfortunately, the gapbetween intention and implementation can be quitewide.
AKA, principal-agent problem
-
-
Local file Local file
-
he task, for researchers, is to expand the evi-dence base for exactly which democratic reformsare the most effective in providing the poor witha productive political voice, so that all people—the poor, insiders, and outsiders—can best takeadvantage of opportunities to effect change whenthey appear.
researchers need to expand the base of evidence for democratization and its benefits
-
Berliner and Erlichshow that political competition, by creating un-certainty over future political control, gaveMexican political parties incentives to undertaketransparency reforms that “serve as insurancemechanisms enabling ruling groups to protecttheir access to government information, and topreserve means of monitoring future incum-bents, in case they lose power” (38)
berkiner and erlich: political competition creates parties that need to compete to win voters and become more accessible
-
uring the19th century, the United Kingdom (like manyWestern countries) extended the vote from wealthylandowners to all males. Lizzeri and Persicoargue that British elites broadened the franchisebecause it better aligned citizen and politicianpolicy preferences, increased the electoral valueof policies with diffuse benefits, and reduced thereturns to politicians from clientelistic policies(32).
UK democratization done by elite and powerful insiders who wanted to have more alignment between politicians and policy solutions + wanted to increase awareness for their problems
-
(i) the poor and disadvantaged who would ben-efit from it, (ii) the economic and political elitewho control the levers of power from withinthe system, and (iii) actors, such as internationaldevelopment and human rights agencies, whoinfluence reform from the outside.
three actors to help with democratic development 1. the poor 2. international actors 3. political and economic elite
-
One way to resolve the dilemma, inspired bythe modernization hypothesis, is to focus onpolicies that affect growth. The main argu-ment of the modernization hypothesis is thatthe social transformations which accompanyeconomic development create more politicallyaware citizens and, thereby, the conditions fordemocratic development (29). Yet, at the levelof cross-country analysis, evidence supportingthis hypothesis remains weak (30)
evidence supporting modernization hypothesisis (economic growth creates social transformations that help the democratic development side) is WEAK
-
Fig. 2. What citizens consider to be an essential characteristic of democracy.
Rich more concerned with voting rights, expressions of free will (Discourse); Poor more concerned with wealth gap and public money
-
Kananga’s governmentrandomized property tax collection across its431 neighborhoods. In taxed neighborhoods within-person collection, collectors went door-to-doorregistering households and collecting the ap-proximately $2 property tax. In control neigh-borhoods, citizens were left to voluntarily payat the tax ministry. All citizens were encouragedto attend government-hosted town hall meetings,where officials and citizens discussed tax andpublic spending in Kananga, and to submit anon-ymous evaluations of the provincial government.The campaign increased the probability ofvisits from tax collectors by 81.5 percentagepoints (from 0.05% in control) and increasedproperty tax compliance by 11.5 percentagepoints (from 0.001% in control)
expanding taxes helps involve citizens more (Kananga)-Weigel
-
Along these lines, Olken reports 20 timeshigher citizen participation and greater citi-zen satisfaction when local village projects inIndonesia were chosen by direct plebisciterather than representative village meetings (28).
Olken data supports plebesites
-
Banerjee et al. investigate this question di-rectly and at scale, in the context of the citygovernment of Delhi, where roughly a third ofthe population of 20 million live in slums (25).Delhi’s elected councilors legislate on how toredistribute state resources, and they also haveaccess to discretionary funds that can be spenton infrastructure. Survey data show a drasticmismatch between councilor spending andcitizen preferences: Although sanitation wasa priority for most slum-dwellers, most moneywent toward road construction. Against thisbackdrop, a random sample of councilors wereinformed 2 years prior to city elections that aleading newspaper would publish report cardson their performance just before the city elec-tion. The informed councilors subsequentlymoved their spending in a pro-poor direction,a move that was rewarded by political parties.
Banerjee et al on the indian slums and the legislator's priorities shifting once a transpareny threat was made
-
idwell et al. conducteda large-scale experiment during the 2012 par-liamentary elections in Sierra Leone, where theyrandomized citizen exposure to pre-electioncandidate debates hosted and screened by athird party (24). Watching debates increasedpolitical knowledge, improved voter-candidatealignment, and increased both the number ofvotes cast and vote shares of the best-performingcandidates.
debate screenings from Bidwell et al lead to more engagement and attention
-
Using data from Brazilian municipalities,Ferraz and Finan showed that the public re-lease of audit reports lowered reelection ratesof mayors from more corrupt municipalities,with more pronounced effects observed inmunicipalities with a local radio station (23)
Ferraz and Finan showed public auditing damaged re-election campaigns in corrupt cities, more information symmetry
-
This,in turn, was associated with a 34% increasein public health care spending over an 8-yearperiod.
Fujiwara's Brazil study. RDD that looked at city's above and below level to have electronic voting and showed that the one's with electronic had more than a 30% increase in public health spending
-
Universal suffrage has been effectively ubiq-uitous in democracies and near-democraciessince 1980, with a handful of exceptions (1). Butcomplex de facto voting procedures often con-strain the ability of the poor to exercise their vote.Using technology to make voting procedures moreaccessible to the less educated can strengthentheir political voice. For example, Brazil historical-ly used a paper ballot system under which it wascommon for more than a quarter of the votes tobe deemed invalid, that is, either blank or error-ridden. In 1998, electronic voting devices wereintroduced to municipalities above a certain pop-ulation threshold, and the electronic interfacewas universally adopted in 2002. By providingvoters step-by-step guidance and introducingvisual aids, this technology facilitated voting byless literate citizens.
helping illiterates learn
-
A growing body of empirical political economypapers use naturally random events or field ex-periments to examine which reforms to demo-cratic institutions can achieve these goals
naturally random events and field experiments to examine which reforms to democratic institutions can achieve the goals we seek
-
A direct implication is that, for the poor, ef-fective democracy requires more than regularlyoccurring elections. It also requires democraticinstitutions that successfully disengage an indi-vidual’s ability to freely exercise her electoralrights from her economic power.
need ability to disengage inddividual's ability to freely exercise electoral rights from economic power
-
In economics, each of these situa-tions embodies a principal-agent problem, inwhich one group (principals) delegates policyimplementation to another group (agents) insettings typified by incomplete information andvarying incentives (19). When the principal hasless information than the agent and the twoparties face differing incentives, the agent candeviate from prescribed actions and, instead,make personally beneficial choices
principal-agent problem in developing states as administrators and agents have different incentives
-
lientel-istic policies
clientelistic policies = patron-client dynamic between rich and poor
-
The political voice afforded the extreme poor indemocracies is typically constrained by eco-nomic and social disadvantage. In many settings,the economic elite can exploit their social con-nections and economic power to provide poo
rich can provide poor with individualized incentives to buy their votes
-
In practice, however, both the rules and theirimplementation depend on how well the stateaccommodates interests of groups with vary-ing economic and political power.
rules and their implemention depend on how well the state accomodates interests of groups with varying economic and political power
-
But fixing the state’s plumbing need not im-ply progressive redistribution. In reality, a stateconsists of groups of actors with often mis-aligned interests—and the state machinery thathas been built for service delivery may not, inpractice, deliver for the poor.
states have actors who often have misaligned interests
-
Duflo has argued for a problem-by-problemapproach: Economists should embrace the roleof “plumbers” and identify ways of improvingthe so-called “plumbing” of the state machinery(8).
Duflo argued for a problem-by=problem approach where economists take on the role of "plumbers" and find new ways of improving the "plumbing" of state capacity
-
nd yet the opposite is true. Sowhy are low- and middle-income democraticstates less responsive to the preferences of theirpoorer citizens? One possible reason is a state’slimited capacity to deliver antipoverty programs.The state may want to redistribute resourcesyet finds itself hobbled by low revenues, lim-ited manpower, and, potentially, a lack of tech-nical know-how (7
middle income states cannot help the poor because -low resources -limited manpower -lack of tech skill
-
If the poor lack the means...to use theirde jure power effectively, then they will failto negotiate a fair share of...growth.”
if the poor lack the means to use their de jure power effectively, then they will fail to negotiate a fair shair of growth
-
Equally poor citizens in middle-incomecountries do not benefit from the same support.This is in part because citizens of rich countriesare reluctant to donate to countries with obviousconcentrations of wealth (a political constraintthat results in, for example, the country incomecriteria that underlie grant and loan program-ming by most bilateral or multilateral aid agen-cies), and so international aid is far less likely totarget the extreme poor in these countries (2).
extreme poor in the middle-income space are often ignored since donors do not want to donate to countries with obvious concentrations of wealth
-
How can the poor securegreater democratic influence when the existing democratic playing field is tilted against them
how can the poor secure greater influence when the existing playing field is tilted against them
-
However, citizens in those countries have not succeeded in using the vote toensure adequate progressive redistribution. Interventions aiming to provide the economically vulnerable withneeded resources must go beyond assisting them directly, they must also improve democratic institutions so thatvulnerable populations themselves can push their representatives to implement redistributive policies
interventions to help economically vulnerable cannot just help them alone, there also needs to be resorces set aside to help improve democratic institutions that can enhance representation for vulnerable populations
-
Millions of the world’s poorest people now live in middle-income democracies that, in theory, could use theirresources to end extreme poverty.
theoretically democracies could help to end extreme poverty, though in practice that is seldom the case
-
-
blackboard.lms.csupueblo.edu blackboard.lms.csupueblo.edu
-
clear indicators of regime legitimacy as opposed to government legitimacy:citizens’ express support for the system as a whole; the degree to which theysupport key institutions of liberal democracy, such as civil rights; their will-ingness to advance their political causes within the existing political sys-tem; and their openness to authoritarian alternatives such as military rule
regime vs government legitimacy
-
-
www-nybooks-com.proxy.uchicago.edu www-nybooks-com.proxy.uchicago.edu
-
The Census Bureau raises the poverty line every year by the same percentage as the increase in the Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers (CPI–U). The CPI–U does not try to measure changes in what people need, or why they think they need it. Nor does it measure changes in what Americans mean when they talk about poverty. The CPI–U just measures changes in prices. But if we want to know how close America has come to eliminating the kind of poverty that existed in 1964, the official measure is supposed to provide an answer. However, the world has also changed in other ways that the official poverty count either ignores or mismeasures. As a result, Figure 1 does not actually tell us much about changes in the kind of poverty that Lyndon Johnson promised to eliminate. Four changes are especially important when we try to measure changes in the poverty rate since 1964.
Role of arbitrary figures
-
-
uchicago.ares.atlas-sys.com uchicago.ares.atlas-sys.com
-
The poverty rate could havedeclined despite the War on Poverty, not because of it.
counterfactual
-
- Mar 2023
-
Local file Local file
-
We observe that the T2 × gender interaction is signifi-cant at p < 0005 in both models. This provides evidencethat women are not more but are less likely than mento sort out of workplaces that explicitly offer nego-tiable wages
women are statistically less likely than men to sort out workplaces that offer negotiable wages
-
Second, interestingly, the gender gap in applicationprobabilities is more pronounced in T1 than in T2.In T1, women’s application probability is 31.9% andmen’s application probability is 46.6%. In contrast,in T2, women’s application probability is slightlyhigher (33.0%; p = 00630, Fisher’s exact test), whereasmen’s application probability is lower (41.2%; p = 00133,Fisher’s exact test). Thus, the gender gap almost halves(from 14.7% to 8.2%) when moving from T1 to T2
gender gap is present around T1 and T2
-
Figure 1 illustrates the application probabilities depend-ing on treatment and gender. First, we observe thatwomen are overall less likely to apply than men (32.5%versus 43.8%; Fisher’s exact test, p < 00001), a generalpattern that is also reported in Flory et al. (2015).
1: women are less likely to apply overall than men
-
Baby Name Guesser,available at http://www.gpeters.com/names/baby-names.php, accessed December 2011), which calcu-lates gender ratios by first name using the Inter-net to analyze patterns of name usage for morethan 100,000 first names.
oh ok
-
hat we advertised, women earned 84.3% ofthe median weekly earnings of their male counterparts(for high-skilled occupations, women earned 80.1% of2 See Online Appendix B for more information on posted wages.(Online appendices available at https://sites.google.com/site/leibbrandt/research.)the median weekly earnings of their male counterparts).In addition, Maxwell (2006) finds that 90% of low-skilled jobs have promotional opportunities. Second,we were able to offer real administrative assistantpositions (and afford to pay salaries). Third, the tasksfor these jobs could be performed at the employees’homes, which rendered it possible to advertise thepositions in different cities and hire individuals fromdifferent cities. One drawback of using administrativeassistant positions is that they are mainly occupied bywomen (79%) and thus may make extrapolations toother jobs difficult where the gender distribution issignificantly different.
choise of admin assistance positions
-
To carry out the 2 × 2 design, we employ a two-stageexperimental method. In the first stage, we adver-tise the position without reference to the contractenvironment. In the second stage, after job seekersexpress interest in the position, we inform them ofthe contract environment and record whether theyultimately choose to apply for the job. These two stepsare important because they allow us to randomizecontract environment across subjects without affectingthe normalcy of the field setting
this is relevant since it can randomize contract environment across subjects without affecting the normalcy of the field setting
-
Our second result is based on sorting into jobs: thegender gap in applications is much more pronouncedfor jobs that leave the negotiation of wage ambiguous.Interestingly, this result is driven by men preferringjobs where negotiation of initial wage is ambiguousrather than when negotiations are expected.
men prefer jobs where initial negotiation is ambiguous
-
A first result is that we findthat when there is no explicit statement that wages arenegotiable, women are more likely to signal their will-ingness to work for a lower wage than advertised andslightly less likely to negotiate a higher wage than men.However, when we explicitly mention the possibilitythat wages are negotiable, these gender differencesvanish completely, suggesting that women react morestrongly to simple changes in the wage description
women will signal for lower when told it's non-negotiable, but will negotiate if they say they price is flexible. Women accept rules more implicitly
-
This investi-gation permits us to compare two quite different, butrelevant, situations: one that is ambiguously structuredso that people arrive at their own interpretations of thesituation and one where the negotiations are muchmore concretely structured. We proceed to investigatethe importance of triggering gender by placing twodistinct ads: one for a “masculine” job task (involvingsports) and the other for a gender-neutral job.
the investigation shows how relevant triggered gender is
-
is its capacity to disentangle twoimportant levels where gender differences in negotia-tion might play a role: (i) sorting into negotiable-salaryworkplaces and (ii) initiation of salary negotiations oncethe person applies.
two different issues at play 1. sorting into negotiable-salary workplaces 2. initiating salary negotiations in general
-
Finally, Babcock and Laschever (2003) report surveyevidence that shows men are four times more likely tonegotiate on first salaries and that individuals who donot negotiate first salaries lose more than $500,000 byage 60.
men are 4x more likely to negotiate on first salaries than individuals who do not negotiate lose more than 500,000 by age 60
-
There is important laboratory and survey evidencesuggesting a quite different determinant of genderdifferences in labor markets: men are significantly morelikely to engage in salary negotiations and are better atthem
men are more used to negotiating and so have higher wages
-
However, when we explicitly mention the possibility that wages are negotiable, these differences disappearcompletely. In terms of sorting, we find that men, in contrast to women, prefer job environments where the “rulesof wage determination” are ambiguous.
men prefer job environemnts where wages are more dynamic, which are often higher paying
-
tural field experiment that randomizes nearly 2,500 job seekers into jobs thatvary important details of the labor contract, we are able to observe both the extent of salary negotiations and thenature of sorting. We find that when there is no explicit statement that wages are negotiable, men are more likelyto negotiate for a higher wage, whereas women are more likely to signal their willingness to work for a lowerwage.
RCT; men show they're willing to negotiate for a higher wage while women are more likely to signal willingness to work for a lower wage
-
-
Local file Local file
-
We should, however, caution the reader that eventhough we find suggestive results, care should be taken when making inferencefrom the data patterns observed herein because several important factors varyacross the two societies. And, we have sampled a limited number of villages.We suspect that our results will not be a universal truth amongst all matrilinealvillages, rather other important factors will interact with matriliny to producethe data patterns observed herein. More research is certainly warranted.
limitation- need more replicability
-
Maasai men com-pete at roughly twice the rate as Maasai women, evidence that is consistentwith data from Western societies that use different tasks and smaller relativestake levels. Yet, this data pattern is reversed among the Khasi, where womenchoose the competitive environment more often than Khasi men
summary
-
The importance of these results should not be under-stated: in both a positive and normative sense, these insights have the potentialto explain important puzzles in economics and in social science more generally.In this study we use an experimental task to explore whether there are genderdifferences in selecting into competitive environments across two distinct soci-eties: the Maasai in Tanzania and the Khasi in India. The societies are uniquein that the Maasai represent an example of a patriarchal society, whereas theKhasi are matrilineal
link between competition and gender is relevant in the social sciences
-
n other words, the cultural choice to displace men or women fromtheir maternal homes, by itself, alters the process of genetic inheritance.
culture choice on whether to uplift men or women can alter genetic inheritence
-
Girlswho imitate the behavior of successful competitive women are more likely tosurvive childhood and will inherit greater wealth if those women are also theirmothers or grandmothers. In turn, their wealth and success make them morepreferable as a model for younger girls (likely their daughters and nieces) andmore likely to have surviving children
idea of role models and aspiration reminds me of Sen
-
The study of gene-culture co-evolution in mathematical modeling suggests thatwhen a particular genetic characteristic favors the transmission of a particularcultural feature, and that cultural feature also increases the fecundity of thegenetic characteristic, evolution can occur at a much faster pac
gene-culture co-evolution
-
Our data show that Khasi women are more likely to choose to compete thanKhasi men. Furthermore, the Khasi women compete more often than Maasaiwomen or any group of women in the various settings in which preferencesfor this type of behavior have been elicited. In the very least, these findingsrepresent existence results: it is not universally true that the average femalein every society avoids competition more often than the average male in thatsociety because we have discovered at least one setting in which this is not true.
the paper's main finding is that the notion of women being less competitive simply will not consistently hold up
-
Overall, if subjects were making inferenceon potential competitors based on the mix they observed, then the effects re-ported in Table IV are consonant with the notion that women are more likelyto compete against other women, especially in matrilineal societies.
in matrilineal societies, women are more likely to compete against other women
-
More importantly for our purposes, roughly half ofthe Khasi subjects opted to compete, whereas only 39 percent of the Maasaichose to compete. When broken down by gender, the underlying force behindthe competitiveness differences across the two societies becomes clear.In the Maasai data, the gender result that we oftentimes observe in the lit-erature is evident: whereas 50 percent of men choose to compete, only 26 per-cent of women select to compete. Alternatively, as Figure 1 highlights, Khasiwomen choose to compete more often than Khasi men—whereas 54 percent ofKhasi women choose to compete, only 39 percent of Khasi men select the com-petitive incentive scheme.
Maasai had a difference of +24 for men; Khasi had +15% for women
-
The experimental task was to toss a tennis ball into a bucket that wasplaced 3 meters away. Participants were informed that they had 10 chances.A successful shot meant that the tennis ball entered the bucket and stayedthere. The task was chosen because it was simple to explain and implement,and no gender differences in ability were expected (as was found in a pilotexperiment and reinforced in the results discussed below). Furthermore, weare aware of no other popular task in these societies that is similar to the ballgames that we implemented.
the game we did in class
-
This attenuated selec-tion problems since everyone was interested in participating in the experimentafter they were made aware of the pecuniary incentives involved. The experi-ment with the Maasai was conducted in two villages in the Arumeru district inthe Arusha region of Tanzania. The experiment with the Khasi was conductedin the Meghalaya region of India. Upon arrival at each experimental site, par-ticipants were directed into one of two groups randomly. These groups wereseparated for the entire experiment
how to attract people to the experiment
-
Khasi men are more important in their sisters’ households thanin their wives’ households, and Maasai women can enjoy prestige and powerin their roles as widows (if they have sons).
some nuance between both groups, duh
-
Age and cattle dominate the Maasai social structure. The most importantdistinctions between men are age-based, and almost all wealth is in cattle. Theage structure prevents men from marrying until they are roughly 30 years oldand polygamy is the most common form of marriage.
Maasai society depiction
-
Though Khasi women do not generally assume the roles held by men in pa-triarchal societies (they do not become warriors or hunters, for example), theyalways live in households in which they or their mothers have authority overmost household decisions. On the other hand, men frequently hold roles thatseem to mirror those of women in patriarchal societies. The Khasi husbanddwells in a household in which he has no authority or property, is expected towork for the gain of his wife’s family, and has no social roles deemed impor-tant.
Khasi women household and the role of men within it
-
In addition, even ordinalclassification of societies on any dimension is dangerous, as culture and societyare not static fixtures handed down from prehistory. Certain reports of extremefemale domination in the Khasi or strong male domination among the Maasaiare somewhat exaggerated and subject to charges of ethnocentrism.
this is a challenge since you're ranking and classifying socieites and creating an imperfect contrast
-
Our experimental results reveal interesting differences in competitiveness:in the patriarchal society, women are less competitive than men, a result con-sistent with student data drawn from Western cultures. Yet, this result reversesin the matrilineal society, where we find that women are more competitive thanmen.
Competitive tendencies verse between patriarchal and matriarchal societies
-
Nevertheless, the role of nurture, or the fact that culture might be criticallylinked to competitive inclinations, is also an important consideration. Morethan a handful of our male readership can likely recall vividly their grammarschool physical education teacher scorning them with the proverbial “you’replaying like a girl” rant to induce greater levels of competitive spirit. Clearly,however, the explanations might not be competing; rather the nature–nurtureinteraction might be of utmost importance, either because nurture enables theexpression of nature
role of nature is nebuous,
-
We use a controlled experiment to explore whether there are gender differencesin selecting into competitive environments across two distinct societies: the Maasaiin Tanzania and the Khasi in India.
Controlled fieldwork to see gender differences in selecting into competitive environments 1. Maasai=very patriarchical 2. Khasi=matriarchal
Maasai men opt to compte at roughly twice the rate as Massai women vs Khasi women choose competitive environment more than Khasi men
-
-
Local file Local file
-
However, in thispaper we have examined an environment where women and menperform equally well and where issues of discrimination or timespent on the job do not have any explanatory power. Nonethelesswe find large gender differences in the propensity to choose com-petitive environments. It appears that these differences aredriven by gender differences in confidence and preferences forentering and performing in a competition. These differences seemsufficiently strong to call for greater attention of standard eco-nomics to explanations of gender differences that so far havemostly been left in the hands of psychologists and sociologists.
seems like there is something deeper going on with gender diffeences since there were so many controls done in this experiment
-
Overall, we find that about 57 percent of the original gendereffect can be accounted for by general differences in overconfi-dence and risk and feedback aversion while the residual “compet-itive” component is 43 percent. This makes clear that the gendergap in choice of compensation scheme is exacerbated when indi-viduals subsequently have to perform under the selected compen-sation scheme.
57% of the original gender effect can be accounted for by general differences in overconfidence and risk feedback aversion
-
An ordered probit of the guessed rank as a function of afemale dummy and performance shows that, conditional on per-formance, women are significantly less confident about their rel-ative ranking than men and that participants with a highertournament performance think they have higher relative perfor-mance (see Table V).1
women much less confident about their relative ranking than men
-
A probit regression reveals that while the participant’s per-formance under the two compensation schemes does not signifi-cantly affect the decision to enter the tournament, the partici-pant’s gender does.
the regression shows performance is not signficant for deciding on tournament entry, but gender is
-
both genders perform significantlybetter under the tournament than the piece rate (one-sided p .01 for each gender separately).
both genders perform significantly better under the tournament than the piece rate
-
As expected we find no gender difference in performanceunder the piece rate or under the tournament. In the piecerate, the average number of problems solved is 10.15 forwomen and 10.68 for men. Using a two-sided t-test, this dif-ference is not significant (p .459). The gender difference inperformance is also not significant in the tournament where,on average, women correctly solve 11.8 problems, and men 12.1(p .643). Throughout the paper the reported test statisticsrefer to a two-sided t-test, unless otherwise noted. The conclu-sions of the reported t-test do not differ from those of a Mann–Whitney test.
no gender difference in perfromance between the piece rate nor the tournament for men and women
-
e selected this five-minute addition task because itrequires both skill and effort and because research suggests thatthere are no gender differences in ability on easy math tests
math based test seelcted because there is no gender difference in ability on easy math tests
-
First, there is evidence that women tend to incorporate negativefeedback more than men (see, e.g., Roberts and Nolen-Hoeksema[1989]). Second, women, more than men, may view a negativesignal as indicative of their self-worth rather than simply theirone-time performance on a task. Women may therefore fall into“confidence traps” from which they do not recover easily (see, e.g.,Dweck [2000] and references therein).
"confidence traps" concept
-
Explanation 4: Men enter the tournament more than womenbecause they are less averse to feedback.
men enter the tournament since they have been conditioned to be less risk averse to feedback
-